Tài liệu Ten Principles of Economics - Part 69 pdf

10 349 0
Tài liệu Ten Principles of Economics - Part 69 pdf

Đang tải... (xem toàn văn)

Thông tin tài liệu

CHAPTER 31 AGGREGATE DEMAND AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY 705 FACT 3: AS OUTPUT FALLS, UNEMPLOYMENT RISES Changes in the economy’s output of goods and services are strongly correlated with changes in the economy’s utilization of its labor force. In other words, when real GDP declines, the rate of unemployment rises. This fact is hardly surprising: When firms choose to produce a smaller quantity of goods and services, they lay off workers, expanding the pool of unemployed. Panel (c) of Figure 31-1 shows the unemployment rate in the U.S. economy since 1965. Once again, recessions are shown as the shaded areas in the figure. The figure shows clearly the impact of recessions on unemployment. In each of the re- cessions, the unemployment rate rises substantially. When the recession ends and real GDP starts to expand, the unemployment rate gradually declines. The unem- ployment rate never approaches zero; instead, it fluctuates around its natural rate of about 5 percent. QUICK QUIZ: List and discuss three key facts about economic fluctuations. EXPLAINING SHORT-RUN ECONOMIC FLUCTUATIONS Describing the regular patterns that economies experience as they fluctuate over time is easy. Explaining what causes these fluctuations is more difficult. Indeed, compared to the topics we have studied in previous chapters, the theory of eco- nomic fluctuations remains controversial. In this and the next two chapters, we de- velop the model that most economists use to explain short-run fluctuations in economic activity. HOW THE SHORT RUN DIFFERS FROM THE LONG RUN In previous chapters we developed theories to explain what determines most im- portant macroeconomic variables in the long run. Chapter 24 explained the level and growth of productivity and real GDP. Chapter 25 explained how the real in- terest rate adjusts to balance saving and investment. Chapter 26 explained why there is always some unemployment in the economy. Chapters 27 and 28 ex- plained the monetary system and how changes in the money supply affect the price level, the inflation rate, and the nominal interest rate. Chapters 29 and 30 ex- tended this analysis to open economies in order to explain the trade balance and the exchange rate. All of this previous analysis was based on two related ideas—the classical di- chotomy and monetary neutrality. Recall that the classical dichotomy is the sepa- ration of variables into real variables (those that measure quantities or relative prices) and nominal variables (those measured in terms of money). According to classical macroeconomic theory, changes in the money supply affect nominal vari- ables but not real variables. As a result of this monetary neutrality, Chapters 24, 25, 706 PART TWELVE SHORT-RUN ECONOMIC FLUCTUATIONS and 26 were able to examine the determinants of real variables (real GDP, the real interest rate, and unemployment) without introducing nominal variables (the money supply and the price level). Do these assumptions of classical macroeconomic theory apply to the world in which we live? The answer to this question is of central importance to under- standing how the economy works: Most economists believe that classical theory de- scribes the world in the long run but not in the short run. Beyond a period of several years, changes in the money supply affect prices and other nominal variables but do not affect real GDP, unemployment, or other real variables. When studying year-to-year changes in the economy, however, the assumption of monetary neu- trality is no longer appropriate. Most economists believe that, in the short run, real and nominal variables are highly intertwined. In particular, changes in the money supply can temporarily push output away from its long-run trend. To understand the economy in the short run, therefore, we need a new model. To build this new model, we rely on many of the tools we have developed in pre- vious chapters, but we have to abandon the classical dichotomy and the neutrality of money. THE BASIC MODEL OF ECONOMIC FLUCTUATIONS Our model of short-run economic fluctuations focuses on the behavior of two vari- ables. The first variable is the economy’s output of goods and services, as mea- sured by real GDP. The second variable is the overall price level, as measured by the CPI or the GDP deflator. Notice that output is a real variable, whereas the price level is a nominal variable. Hence, by focusing on the relationship between these two variables, we are highlighting the breakdown of the classical dichotomy. We analyze fluctuations in the economy as a whole with the model of aggre- gate demand and aggregate supply, which is illustrated in Figure 31-2. On the ver- tical axis is the overall price level in the economy. On the horizontal axis is the overall quantity of goods and services. The aggregate-demand curve shows the quantity of goods and services that households, firms, and the government want to buy at each price level. The aggregate-supply curve shows the quantity of goods and services that firms produce and sell at each price level. According to this model, the price level and the quantity of output adjust to bring aggregate de- mand and aggregate supply into balance. It may be tempting to view the model of aggregate demand and aggregate supply as nothing more than a large version of the model of market demand and market supply, which we introduced in Chapter 4. Yet in fact this model is quite different. When we consider demand and supply in a particular market—ice cream, for instance—the behavior of buyers and sellers depends on the ability of resources to move from one market to another. When the price of ice cream rises, the quantity demanded falls because buyers will use their incomes to buy prod- ucts other than ice cream. Similarly, a higher price of ice cream raises the quantity supplied because firms that produce ice cream can increase production by hiring workers away from other parts of the economy. This microeconomic substitution from one market to another is impossible when we are analyzing the economy as a whole. After all, the quantity that our model is trying to explain—real GDP— measures the total quantity produced in all of the economy’s markets. To under- stand why the aggregate-demand curve is downward sloping and why the model of aggregate demand and aggregate supply the model that most economists use to explain short-run fluctuations in economic activity around its long-run trend aggregate-demand curve a curve that shows the quantity of goods and services that households, firms, and the government want to buy at each price level aggregate-supply curve a curve that shows the quantity of goods and services that firms choose to produce and sell at each price level CHAPTER 31 AGGREGATE DEMAND AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY 707 aggregate-supply curve is upward sloping, we need a macroeconomic theory. Developing such a theory is our next task. QUICK QUIZ: How does the economy’s behavior in the short run differ from its behavior in the long run? ◆ Draw the model of aggregate demand and aggregate supply. What variables are on the two axes? THE AGGREGATE-DEMAND CURVE The aggregate-demand curve tells us the quantity of all goods and services de- manded in the economy at any given price level. As Figure 31-3 illustrates, the aggregate-demand curve is downward sloping. This means that, other things equal, a fall in the economy’s overall level of prices (from, say, P 1 to P 2 ) tends to raise the quantity of goods and services demanded (from Y 1 to Y 2 ). WHY THE AGGREGATE-DEMAND CURVE SLOPES DOWNWARD Why does a fall in the price level raise the quantity of goods and services de- manded? To answer this question, it is useful to recall that GDP (which we denote as Y) is the sum of consumption (C), investment (I), government purchases (G), and net exports (NX): Equilibrium output Quantity of Output Price Level 0 Equilibrium price level Aggregate supply Aggregate demand Figure 31-2 A GGREGATE D EMAND AND A GGREGATE S UPPLY . Economists use the model of aggregate demand and aggregate supply to analyze economic fluctuations. On the vertical axis is the overall level of prices. On the horizontal axis is the economy’s total output of goods and services. Output and the price level adjust to the point at which the aggregate-supply and aggregate-demand curves intersect. 708 PART TWELVE SHORT-RUN ECONOMIC FLUCTUATIONS Y ϭ C ϩ I ϩ G ϩ NX. Each of these four components contributes to the aggregate demand for goods and services. For now, we assume that government spending is fixed by policy. The other three components of spending—consumption, investment, and net ex- ports—depend on economic conditions and, in particular, on the price level. To un- derstand the downward slope of the aggregate-demand curve, therefore, we must examine how the price level affects the quantity of goods and services demanded for consumption, investment, and net exports. The Price Level and Consumption: The Wealth Effect Con- sider the money that you hold in your wallet and your bank account. The nominal value of this money is fixed, but its real value is not. When prices fall, these dollars are more valuable because then they can be used to buy more goods and services. Thus, a decrease in the price level makes consumers feel more wealthy, which in turn en- courages them to spend more. The increase in consumer spending means a larger quantity of goods and services demanded. The Price Level and Investment: The Interest-Rate Effect As we discussed in Chapter 28, the price level is one determinant of the quantity of money demanded. The lower the price level, the less money households need to hold to buy the goods and services they want. When the price level falls, therefore, households try to reduce their holdings of money by lending some of it out. For in- stance, a household might use its excess money to buy interest-bearing bonds. Or it might deposit its excess money in an interest-bearing savings account, and the bank would use these funds to make more loans. In either case, as households try to convert some of their money into interest-bearing assets, they drive down Quantity of Output Price Level 0 Aggregate demand P 1 Y 1 Y 2 P 2 1. A decrease in the price level . . . 2. . . . increases the quantity of goods and services demanded. Figure 31-3 T HE A GGREGATE -D EMAND C URVE . A fall in the price level from P 1 to P 2 increases the quantity of goods and services demanded from Y 1 to Y 2 . There are three reasons for this negative relationship. As the price level falls, real wealth rises, interest rates fall, and the exchange rate depreciates. These effects stimulate spending on consumption, investment, and net exports. Increased spending on these components of output means a larger quantity of goods and services demanded. CHAPTER 31 AGGREGATE DEMAND AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY 709 interest rates. Lower interest rates, in turn, encourage borrowing by firms that want to invest in new plants and equipment and by households who want to in- vest in new housing. Thus, a lower price level reduces the interest rate, encourages greater spending on investment goods, and thereby increases the quantity of goods and services demanded. The Price Level and Net Exports: The Exchange-Rate Ef- fect As we have just discussed, a lower price level in the United States lowers the U.S. interest rate. In response, some U.S. investors will seek higher returns by investing abroad. For instance, as the interest rate on U.S. government bonds falls, a mutual fund might sell U.S. government bonds in order to buy German govern- ment bonds. As the mutual fund tries to move assets overseas, it increases the sup- ply of dollars in the market for foreign-currency exchange. The increased supply of dollars causes the dollar to depreciate relative to other currencies. Because each dollar buys fewer units of foreign currencies, foreign goods become more expen- sive relative to domestic goods. This change in the real exchange rate (the relative price of domestic and foreign goods) increases U.S. exports of goods and services and decreases U.S. imports of goods and services. Net exports, which equal ex- ports minus imports, also increase. Thus, when a fall in the U.S. price level causes U.S. interest rates to fall, the real exchange rate depreciates, and this depreciation stimulates U.S. net exports and thereby increases the quantity of goods and services demanded. Summary There are, therefore, three distinct but related reasons why a fall in the price level increases the quantity of goods and services demanded: (1) Con- sumers feel wealthier, which stimulates the demand for consumption goods. (2) Interest rates fall, which stimulates the demand for investment goods. (3) The ex- change rate depreciates, which stimulates the demand for net exports. For all three reasons, the aggregate-demand curve slopes downward. It is important to keep in mind that the aggregate-demand curve (like all de- mand curves) is drawn holding “other things equal.” In particular, our three ex- planations of the downward-sloping aggregate-demand curve assume that the money supply is fixed. That is, we have been considering how a change in the price level affects the demand for goods and services, holding the amount of money in the economy constant. As we will see, a change in the quantity of money shifts the aggregate-demand curve. At this point, just keep in mind that the aggregate-demand curve is drawn for a given quantity of money. WHY THE AGGREGATE-DEMAND CURVE MIGHT SHIFT The downward slope of the aggregate-demand curve shows that a fall in the price level raises the overall quantity of goods and services demanded. Many other fac- tors, however, affect the quantity of goods and services demanded at a given price level. When one of these other factors changes, the aggregate-demand curve shifts. Let’s consider some examples of events that shift aggregate demand. We can categorize them according to which component of spending is most directly affected. Shifts Arising from Consumption Suppose Americans suddenly be- come more concerned about saving for retirement and, as a result, reduce their current consumption. Because the quantity of goods and services demanded at 710 PART TWELVE SHORT-RUN ECONOMIC FLUCTUATIONS any price level is lower, the aggregate-demand curve shifts to the left. Conversely, imagine that a stock market boom makes people feel wealthy and less concerned about saving. The resulting increase in consumer spending means a greater quan- tity of goods and services demanded at any given price level, so the aggregate- demand curve shifts to the right. Thus, any event that changes how much people want to consume at a given price level shifts the aggregate-demand curve. One policy variable that has this effect is the level of taxation. When the government cuts taxes, it encourages people to spend more, so the aggregate-demand curve shifts to the right. When the government raises taxes, people cut back on their spending, and the aggregate- demand curve shifts to the left. Shifts Arising from Investment Any event that changes how much firms want to invest at a given price level also shifts the aggregate-demand curve. For instance, imagine that the computer industry introduces a faster line of computers, and many firms decide to invest in new computer systems. Because the quantity of goods and services demanded at any price level is higher, the aggregate-demand curve shifts to the right. Conversely, if firms become pes- simistic about future business conditions, they may cut back on investment spend- ing, shifting the aggregate-demand curve to the left. Tax policy can also influence aggregate demand through investment. As we saw in Chapter 25, an investment tax credit (a tax rebate tied to a firm’s investment spending) increases the quantity of investment goods that firms demand at any given interest rate. It therefore shifts the aggregate-demand curve to the right. The repeal of an investment tax credit reduces investment and shifts the aggregate- demand curve to the left. Another policy variable that can influence investment and aggregate demand is the money supply. As we discuss more fully in the next chapter, an increase in the money supply lowers the interest rate in the short run. This makes borrow- ing less costly, which stimulates investment spending and thereby shifts the aggregate-demand curve to the right. Conversely, a decrease in the money supply raises the interest rate, discourages investment spending, and thereby shifts the aggregate-demand curve to the left. Many economists believe that throughout U.S. history changes in monetary policy have been an important source of shifts in ag- gregate demand. Shifts Arising from Government Purchases The most direct way that policymakers shift the aggregate-demand curve is through government pur- chases. For example, suppose Congress decides to reduce purchases of new weapons systems. Because the quantity of goods and services demanded at any price level is lower, the aggregate-demand curve shifts to the left. Conversely, if state governments start building more highways, the result is a greater quantity of goods and services demanded at any price level, so the aggregate-demand curve shifts to the right. Shifts Arising from Net Exports Any event that changes net exports for a given price level also shifts aggregate demand. For instance, when Europe ex- periences a recession, it buys fewer goods from the United States. This reduces U.S. net exports and shifts the aggregate-demand curve for the U.S. economy to CHAPTER 31 AGGREGATE DEMAND AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY 711 the left. When Europe recovers from its recession, it starts buying U.S. goods again, shifting the aggregate-demand curve to the right. Net exports sometimes change because of movements in the exchange rate. Suppose, for instance, that international speculators bid up the value of the U.S. dollar in the market for foreign-currency exchange. This appreciation of the dollar would make U.S. goods more expensive compared to foreign goods, which would depress net exports and shift the aggregate-demand curve to the left. Conversely, a depreciation of the dollar stimulates net exports and shifts the aggregate- demand curve to the right. Summary In the next chapter we analyze the aggregate-demand curve in more detail. There we examine more precisely how the tools of monetary and fis- cal policy can shift aggregate demand and whether policymakers should use these tools for that purpose. At this point, however, you should have some idea about why the aggregate-demand curve slopes downward and what kinds of events and policies can shift this curve. Table 31-1 summarizes what we have learned so far. Table 31-1 T HE A GGREGATE -D EMAND C URVE : S UMMARY W HY D OES THE A GGREGATE -D EMAND C URVE S LOPE D OWNWARD ? 1. The Wealth Effect: A lower price level increases real wealth, which encourages spending on consumption. 2. The Interest-Rate Effect: A lower price level reduces the interest rate, which encourages spending on investment. 3. The Exchange-Rate Effect: A lower price level causes the real exchange rate to depreciate, which encourages spending on net exports. W HY M IGHT THE A GGREGATE -D EMAND C URVE S HIFT ? 1. Shifts Arising from Consumption: An event that makes consumers spend more at a given price level (a tax cut, a stock market boom) shifts the aggregate- demand curve to the right. An event that makes consumers spend less at a given price level (a tax hike, a stock market decline) shifts the aggregate- demand curve to the left. 2. Shifts Arising from Investment: An event that makes firms invest more at a given price level (optimism about the future, a fall in interest rates due to an increase in the money supply) shifts the aggregate-demand curve to the right. An event that makes firms invest less at a given price level (pessimism about the future, a rise in interest rates due to a decrease in the money supply) shifts the aggregate-demand curve to the left. 3. Shifts Arising from Government Purchases: An increase in government purchases of goods and services (greater spending on defense or highway construction) shifts the aggregate-demand curve to the right. A decrease in government purchases on goods and services (a cutback in defense or highway spending) shifts the aggregate-demand curve to the left. 4. Shifts Arising from Net Exports: An event that raises spending on net exports at a given price level (a boom overseas, an exchange-rate depreciation) shifts the aggregate-demand curve to the right. An event that reduces spending on net exports at a given price level (a recession overseas, an exchange-rate appreciation) shifts the aggregate-demand curve to the left. 712 PART TWELVE SHORT-RUN ECONOMIC FLUCTUATIONS QUICK QUIZ: Explain the three reasons why the aggregate-demand curve slopes downward. ◆ Give an example of an event that would shift the aggregate-demand curve. Which way would this event shift the curve? THE AGGREGATE-SUPPLY CURVE The aggregate-supply curve tells us the total quantity of goods and services that firms produce and sell at any given price level. Unlike the aggregate-demand curve, which is always downward sloping, the aggregate-supply curve shows a relationship that depends crucially on the time horizon being examined. In the long run, the aggregate-supply curve is vertical, whereas in the short run, the aggregate-supply curve is upward sloping. To understand short-run economic fluctuations, and how the short-run behavior of the economy deviates from its long-run behavior, we need to examine both the long-run aggregate-supply curve and the short-run aggregate-supply curve. WHY THE AGGREGATE-SUPPLY CURVE IS VERTICAL IN THE LONG RUN What determines the quantity of goods and services supplied in the long run? We implicitly answered this question earlier in the book when we analyzed the process of economic growth. In the long run, an economy’s production of goods and ser- vices (its real GDP) depends on its supplies of labor, capital, and natural resources and on the available technology used to turn these factors of production into goods and services. Because the price level does not affect these long-run determinants of real GDP, the long-run aggregate-supply curve is vertical, as in Figure 31-4. In other words, in the long run, the economy’s labor, capital, natural resources, and technology de- termine the total quantity of goods and services supplied, and this quantity sup- plied is the same regardless of what the price level happens to be. The vertical long-run aggregate-supply curve is, in essence, just an application of the classical dichotomy and monetary neutrality. As we have already discussed, classical macroeconomic theory is based on the assumption that real variables do not depend on nominal variables. The long-run aggregate-supply curve is consis- tent with this idea because it implies that the quantity of output (a real variable) does not depend on the level of prices (a nominal variable). As noted earlier, most economists believe that this principle works well when studying the economy over a period of many years, but not when studying year-to-year changes. Thus, the aggregate-supply curve is vertical only in the long run. One might wonder why supply curves for specific goods and services can be upward sloping if the long-run aggregate-supply curve is vertical. The reason is that the supply of specific goods and services depends on relative prices—the prices of those goods and services compared to other prices in the economy. For example, when the price of ice cream rises, suppliers of ice cream increase their production, taking labor, milk, chocolate, and other inputs away from the production of other goods, such as frozen yogurt. By contrast, the economy’s overall production of CHAPTER 31 AGGREGATE DEMAND AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY 713 goods and services is limited by its labor, capital, natural resources, and tech- nology. Thus, when all prices in the economy rise together, there is no change in the overall quantity of goods and services supplied. WHY THE LONG-RUN AGGREGATE- SUPPLY CURVE MIGHT SHIFT The position of the long-run aggregate-supply curve shows the quantity of goods and services predicted by classical macroeconomic theory. This level of production is sometimes called potential output or full-employment output. To be more accurate, we call it the natural rate of output because it shows what the economy produces when unemployment is at its natural, or normal, rate. The natural rate of output is the level of production toward which the economy gravitates in the long run. Any change in the economy that alters the natural rate of output shifts the long-run aggregate-supply curve. Because output in the classical model depends on labor, capital, natural resources, and technological knowledge, we can catego- rize shifts in the long-run aggregate-supply curve as arising from these sources. Shifts Arising from Labor Imagine that an economy experiences an in- crease in immigration from abroad. Because there would be a greater number of workers, the quantity of goods and services supplied would increase. As a result, the long-run aggregate-supply curve would shift to the right. Conversely, if many workers left the economy to go abroad, the long-run aggregate-supply curve would shift to the left. The position of the long-run aggregate-supply curve also depends on the nat- ural rate of unemployment, so any change in the natural rate of unemployment shifts the long-run aggregate-supply curve. For example, if Congress were to raise Quantity of Output Natural rate of output Price Level 0 Long-run aggregate supply P 2 1. A change in the price level . . . 2. . . . does not affect the quantity of goods and services supplied in the long run. P 1 Figure 31-4 T HE L ONG -R UN A GGREGATE - S UPPLY C URVE . In the long run, the quantity of output supplied depends on the economy’s quantities of labor, capital, and natural resources and on the technology for turning these inputs into output. The quantity supplied does not depend on the overall price level. As a result, the long-run aggregate-supply curve is vertical at the natural rate of output. 714 PART TWELVE SHORT-RUN ECONOMIC FLUCTUATIONS the minimum wage substantially, the natural rate of unemployment would rise, and the economy would produce a smaller quantity of goods and services. As a result, the long-run aggregate-supply curve would shift to the left. Conversely, if a reform of the unemployment insurance system were to encourage unemployed workers to search harder for new jobs, the natural rate of unemployment would fall, and the long-run aggregate-supply curve would shift to the right. Shifts Arising from Capital An increase in the economy’s capital stock increases productivity and, thereby, the quantity of goods and services supplied. As a result, the long-run aggregate-supply curve shifts to the right. Conversely, a decrease in the economy’s capital stock decreases productivity and the quantity of goods and services supplied, shifting the long-run aggregate-supply curve to the left. Notice that the same logic applies regardless of whether we are discussing physical capital or human capital. An increase either in the number of machines or in the number of college degrees will raise the economy’s ability to produce goods and services. Thus, either would shift the long-run aggregate-supply curve to the right. Shifts Arising from Natural Resources An economy’s production depends on its natural resources, including its land, minerals, and weather. A dis- covery of a new mineral deposit shifts the long-run aggregate-supply curve to the right. A change in weather patterns that makes farming more difficult shifts the long-run aggregate-supply curve to the left. In many countries, important natural resources are imported from abroad. A change in the availability of these resources can also shift the aggregate-supply curve. As we discuss later in this chapter, events occurring in the world oil market have historically been an important source of shifts in aggregate supply. Shifts Arising from Technological Knowledge Perhaps the most important reason that the economy today produces more than it did a generation ago is that our technological knowledge has advanced. The invention of the com- puter, for instance, has allowed us to produce more goods and services from any given amounts of labor, capital, and natural resources. As a result, it has shifted the long-run aggregate-supply curve to the right. Although not literally technological, there are many other events that act like changes in technology. As Chapter 9 explains, opening up international trade has effects similar to inventing new production processes, so it also shifts the long- run aggregate-supply curve to the right. Conversely, if the government passed new regulations preventing firms from using some production methods, perhaps because they were too dangerous for workers, the result would be a leftward shift in the long-run aggregate-supply curve. Summary The long-run aggregate-supply curve reflects the classical model of the economy we developed in previous chapters. Any policy or event that raised real GDP in previous chapters can now be viewed as increasing the quantity of goods and services supplied and shifting the long-run aggregate-supply curve to the right. Any policy or event that lowered real GDP in previous chapters can now . aggregate-demand curve (like all de- mand curves) is drawn holding “other things equal.” In particular, our three ex- planations of the downward-sloping. the short-run behavior of the economy deviates from its long-run behavior, we need to examine both the long-run aggregate-supply curve and the short-run aggregate-supply

Ngày đăng: 24/12/2013, 17:15

Từ khóa liên quan

Tài liệu cùng người dùng

Tài liệu liên quan