age of inflation continued exposes criminal monetary policies of us federal reserve phần 2 pps

10 192 0
age of inflation continued exposes criminal monetary policies of us federal reserve phần 2 pps

Đang tải... (xem toàn văn)

Thông tin tài liệu

The Dollar Standard We may not be able to see the future, but we can always learn from the past. A cursory look at the history of international monetary systems may reveal where we were, where we are, and where we are heading. Ever since the dawn of civilization, precious metals have had wide monetary use, due to their convenience of handling, durability, divisibility, and their high value as jewelry. During the Middle Ages, European countries strove toward bimetallism, that is, the use of gold and silver as the monetary standard of value. The United States government adopted a bimetallic standard at its very beginning and clung to it throughout most of the 19 th century. England was the first country that made gold the standard currency in 1798 and 1816; many countries hesitantly followed suit, the United States in 1900. Under this system, gold became the standard of value throughout the commercial world, furnishing a price denominator for all goods and services. Gold coins passed freely from hand to hand in full payment for economic goods and in discharge of indebtedness. They had no regional or national limitation, being accepted and traded all over the globe. The age of the classical gold standard was rather short; it came to an abrupt end in 1914 when World War I erupted in Europe. The belligerent governments immediately revoked their 8 The Dollar Standard redemption obligations, enabling them to issue money freely and generously. After the war, while the vanquished countries continued to inflate their currencies at accelerating rates until they became practically worthless, the victors soon replaced the coin standard with a bullion standard which used gold in the form of bars and ingots in international payment. The Great Depression soon smothered this system with massive budget deficits and numerous regulations and controls. At the Bretton Woods international conference in 1944, the representatives of allied nations tried to restore monetary order by creating yet another system, the gold-exchange standard. The member countries fixed the value of their currencies not to gold, but to some foreign exchange, which in turn was redeemable in gold at a given ratio. Most governments fixed their currencies to the U.S. dollar and retained dollar reserves in the United States. In fact, they created an incipient dollar standard resting on gold. It served satisfactorily during the 1950s, facilitating numerous readjustments to the dollar, but came under severe pressure during the 1960s when President Johnson introduced his Great Society and waged war in Vietnam. Massive budget deficits, which the Federal Reserve readily facilitated, soon weakened international confidence in the integrity of the dollar, which led some dollar- holding countries to seek exchange of their dollars for gold. With the specter of U.S. international insolvency coming in sight, and in order to avoid the unthinkable, the U.S. government, in 1968, introduced a two-tier system, which limited payment of gold to foreign central banks at $35 an ounce, but denied gold payment to all others. And in support of the waning U.S. gold reserves, the International Monetary Fund created Special Drawing Rights as a new currency reserve. Despite all such measures, the drain on U.S. gold reserves continued. The year 1971 was to be a landmark in monetary history. On August 15, the United States government removed gold as the foundation stone of the international monetary order and 9 Age of Inflation Continued rescinded the international agreements that had defined the system since the end of World War II. In a nationally televised address, President Nixon simply announced that the United States would no longer honor its 26-year-old commitment to pay international obligations in gold at the rate of $35 an ounce. He imposed a 10 percent surcharge on imports into the United States and, above all, ordered virtually all wages and prices to freeze. Violators would be fined, imprisoned, or both. When the controls created frustrating problems, they underwent four "phases" of adjustment to "problem areas" such as food, health care, and construction. The new fiat-dollar standard was a germane derivative of the Bretton Woods order, without its limitations. Liberated at last from any gold reserve requirement, it promised to serve all political needs. Unfortunately, it proved to be even less stable than its harbinger, more inflationary and, above all, more divisive and injurious to American prosperity and prestige. Withdrawal of American troops from Vietnam in 1972 and 1973 did not end the price and wage spirals that were to mark the presidencies of Messrs Nixon, Ford, and Carter. With the federal government incurring massive budget deficits, the Federal Reserve duly supplied funds at single-digit interest rates, bank credit expanded at double-digit rates, and goods prices soared. The Fed occasionally would "tighten" its reins, but its rates always remained below market rates, often even below the rates of inflation. U.S. trade deficits increased erratically with dollar funds flowing to Western Europe and Japan, but the monetary authorities in Europe and Japan liked the exchange rates and defended them with substantial purchases of dollars. Their dollar support meant to sustain their own exports and to bolster and subsidize their own export industries. The abundance of dollar funds in central banks throughout the world then facilitated an explosive growth of money and credit in most industrial countries. In 1974 and 1975, the fever of double-digit inflation was 10 The Dollar Standard briefly eclipsed by the chills of recession. American unemployment rose to 8.3 percent, a 33-year-high nationally, and much higher in construction and manufacturing. It remained high although the chills of recession soon gave way again to the fever of inflation. Money and credit were made to expand again at double-digit rates, trade deficits set new records, and the U.S. dollar deteriorated further in international markets. By the end of the decade, the country fell again into the grip of the twin economic evils of recession and inflation. Unemployment rose again while GNP was falling. The Federal Reserve, under new management, finally meant to call a halt to the foment. It raised its discount rate to 12 percent, the prime rate rose above 15 percent, and the eurodollar rate to 20 percent. President Carter joined the campaign by imposing federal temperature controls in public and commercial buildings, setting minimum summer temperature at 78 degrees and maximum winter temperature at 65 degrees. Many Americans keenly felt the effects of gasoline rationing, waiting in long lines at gasoline service stations. Legislators and regulators had a ready explanation for the crisis: the sheikhs and emirs of OPEC had done it again. In 1981, President Reagan took the helm of a deeply troubled country. During his eight years in office he managed to lift the spirits, changing the course, and relaxing the reins of government. He rolled back the Johnson Great Society but preserved the Roosevelt New Deal. He rejected Keynesian formulas for managing economic demand and instead followed "supply-side" prescriptions which aim to stimulate production and investment by way of tax reduction and removal of some government controls. Mostly at loggerheads with Congress, he insisted on rearming the country and confronting Soviet aspirations. He steadfastly resisted Congressional efforts to boost taxes significantly. With Congress raising social spending and the President expanding military outlays, Federal budget deficits soon exceeded two hundred billion dollars a year; the national debt doubled in seven years. 11 Age of Inflation Continued With the discount rate at 12 percent, the quantity of money and credit finally stabilized, allowing the economy to readjust to actual market conditions. A 25 percent Federal tax cut over three years brought some relief to business but tore big holes in the federal budget and capital market. The dollar regained some relative strength and the American economy became again the engine of the world economy. It slowed down after a spectacular Wall Street crash in 1987, which reflected the international concern about the budget deficits and the chronic trade and current account deficits of the United States. In ages past, the creditors would have demanded prompt payment in gold, which would have forced the debtor to mend his ways or face insolvency. The fiat dollar standard merely prompted contentious diplomatic exchanges—the creditors pressing the debtor to live within his means and the debtor urging his creditors to relax and stimulate their own economies with easier money, larger budget deficits, or both. The decade of the 1990s was akin to the 1980s. It began with a recession, saw new acceleration followed by deceleration and a "soft landing" in 1995. Great concern about the large balance of payments deficits of the United States led to a sharp decline in the value of the U.S. dollar, especially versus the Japanese yen and the Deutsche mark, along with other European currencies closely tied to it. Coordinated intervention by foreign central banks was needed to stabilize the dollar. It rallied for a while when several Asian currencies foundered in 1997. Large current-account deficits led to sudden declines and devaluations of the Thai baht, the Malaysian ringgit, the Indonesian rupiah, the Philippine peso, the Singapore dollar, and the South Korean won. The International Monetary Fund (IMF), working in cooperation with industrial countries, kept the Asian crisis from spreading. Throughout the 1990s, the Federal government suffered budget deficits, although political spokesmen frequently boasted of surpluses. In 1998, 1999, and 2000 the Clinton Administration waxed eloquent about its surpluses which, in time, would retire the 12 The Dollar Standard national debt. In reality, the surpluses were deficits financed with Social Security money and other government trust funds. They increased the national debt with Social Security IOUs by as much as they did with Treasury bills, notes, and bonds sold to investors; payment obligations to Social Security beneficiaries are as binding as those to investors. * * * Throughout the decades, a few economists were worried about the magnitude of the trade deficits and the vulnerability of the American dollar, but their fears proved to be unfounded because they underestimated the worldwide demand for dollars and the willingness of foreign investors and central bankers to trust and hold U.S. dollars. After all, until recently, the deficits never exceeded three percent of GDP and Americans still were net creditors in their foreign accounts. By now, in 2006, the dollar standard has reached a stage in which not only a few economists, but also some foreign creditors, are beginning to question its future. The Federal government is swimming in an ocean of debt. In its first term, the Bush administration increased the federal debt by $2.2 trillion. Congress raised the Treasury debt ceiling three times, by $450 billion in 2002, by $984 billion in 2003, and by another $800 billion on November 19, 2004, to $8,184 trillion. The ready willingness of Congress to finance such deficits is a clear indication of the political and ideological mold-and-make-up of most members of Congress, and the public that elects them. Foreign observers are drawing similar conclusions. The Bank of Japan, which owns more than $800 billion in dollar obligations, already announced its reluctance to increase its holding. China, with dollar holdings exceeding $500 billion, is laboring under "unsustainable U.S. trade deficits." Asian banks, altogether holding more than $2 trillion in American obligations, are suffering hundred-billion dollar losses in terms of purchasing power. It is not surprising that the central banks of India and Russia, as well as some Middle East investors, have begun to sell 13 Age of Inflation Continued dollar obligations. According to some estimates, foreign banks and investors are holding some $9 trillion of U.S. paper assets. They are owning some 43 percent of U.S. Treasuries, 25 percent of American corporate bonds, and 12 percent of U.S. corporate equities. They obviously are suffering losses whenever the dollar falls against their respective currencies; even if they are pegged to the dollar, they are incurring losses against all other currencies that are rising. The dollar standard surely would draw to a close if foreign dollar investors would panic and start selling their American paper investments—their U.S. Treasuries, U.S. agencies, and corporate bonds and shares. The crash would be felt around the world and neither foreign sellers nor American authorities could be trusted to react rationally in the fear and noise of the crash. The scene could be similar to the political bedlam of the 1930s. There always is the hope that the primary creditors will act in concert and once again bail out the debtor. The European Central Bank, the Bank of Japan, the Bank of China, and the Bank of England may decide to avert the unthinkable and support the dollar by mopping up huge quantities. The mopping would stabilize the situation once again by inflating and depreciating their own currencies; they would pass the depreciation losses on to their own nationals. Optimists in our midst are hoping for this scenario; they are convinced that the Bush administration will in time save the situation by balancing its budget and the Federal Reserve will allow interest rates to seek market levels. Such a policy would avert the dollar dilemma, although it would lead to a painful recession forcing all economic factors to readjust to changing market conditions. Pessimists in our midst cast doubt on such a scenario. They point not only to the host of legislators and regulators who cherish their position and power, but also to public opinion and ideology, which call for government favors. They are prepared to proceed on the present road and brace for the morrow. A few cynics even 14 The Dollar Standard contend that a government facing a financial crisis of such magnitude is prone to divert public attention from its ominous path by embarking upon foreign adventures. This economist is ever mindful that debts do not fade or pass away. Individuals must face them, deal with them, or renege in bankruptcy. Governments have an additional option: as the issuers of their own currencies, they may inflate and depreciate their debts away. The United States government has done this ever since it cast aside the gold standard and imposed the dollar standard. It undoubtedly will continue to do so as far as the eye can see. It proceeds on an iniquitous road which individuals would soon be barred from traveling, but governments love to take, shedding their debts one percent at a time. It is a road of the dollar standard designed at Bretton Woods, built by the U.S. government, managed by the Federal Reserve System, and financed largely by creditor central banks in Europe and Asia. It is a road on which the fall in dollar value has inflicted losses not only on all foreign dollar holders, each in proportion to the amount of dollars held, but also on virtually all Americans. It is the political road of debt default, the magnitude of which amounts to trillions of dollars, undoubtedly the largest in the history of international relations. It will be remembered for generations to come. It is unlikely that the Federal government and the Federal Reserve will soon mend their ways, but it also is doubtful that foreign creditors will continue their support indefinitely. The U.S. dollar is bound to continue to depreciate and gradually surrender its role as the world's primary reserve currency to a multiple reserve-currency system resting on the euro, Japanese yen, Chinese renminbi, and the American dollar. The multiple- standard system is likely to perform more efficiently and equitably than the dollar standard. Competition would avoid the abuses and inequities of a monopolistic system. Confining the powers of the Federal Reserve System and constraining the deficit aptitude of the U.S. Treasury, it would ward off any further inundation of the 15 Age of Inflation Continued world with U.S. dollars. In idle reverie of years long past, this economist is tempted to compare the dollar standard with the gold standard. Throughout the short history of the gold standard, the balance of payments of gold-producing countries was usually "unfavorable." Since the birth of the dollar standard, the United States has assumed the position of the gold-producing countries; its balance of payments usually is unfavorable. Much capital and labor were spent to find, mine, refine, and market gold; the United States bears minuscule expense in the production of its money. The quantity of gold coming to market was limited by market forces; the quantity of dollars depends on the judgment of Federal Reserve governors who are appointed by the President. In times of turmoil and war, the quantity of gold mined declines; in such times the stock of fiat dollars tends to multiply and its value depreciates accordingly. The quantity of gold is limited by nature and its value is enhanced by many non-monetary uses; fiat and fiduciary moneys have no such uses or limitations. They are the sorry products of politics. 16 Deep in Debt, Deep in Danger In a question-and-answer session conducted in September, 2004, a professor of economics responded to student questions about disturbing reports of excessive spending and dangerous levels of debt. Student: The Federal government is about to reach the Congressional debt limit of $7.384 trillion. Should I be concerned about this debt? My history professor likes to quote President Franklin D. Roosevelt who once said: "Our national debt, after all, is an internal debt owed not only by the nation but to the nation. If our children have to pay interest on it, they will pay that interest to themselves." Professor: In 1939, when President Roosevelt made that speech, the Federal debt may have been an internal debt, but it surely was not owed to ourselves. It divided the nation between people who enjoyed the benefits of spending, and their descendants, who were expected to square the account; it created a persistent social conflict. Since the 1980s, we have added a rapidly growing international debt. It is estimated at some $5.5 trillion, which amounts to one-half of our gross national product of some $11 trillion. Americans would have to labor half a year in order to pay it off. It is significant that our foreign creditors like to invest their dollar earnings in U.S. Treasury obligations, which 17 . foundation stone of the international monetary order and 9 Age of Inflation Continued rescinded the international agreements that had defined the system since the end of World War II. In. an ocean of debt. In its first term, the Bush administration increased the federal debt by $2. 2 trillion. Congress raised the Treasury debt ceiling three times, by $450 billion in 20 02, by $984. $9 trillion of U.S. paper assets. They are owning some 43 percent of U.S. Treasuries, 25 percent of American corporate bonds, and 12 percent of U.S. corporate equities. They obviously are suffering

Ngày đăng: 14/08/2014, 22:20

Từ khóa liên quan

Tài liệu cùng người dùng

  • Đang cập nhật ...

Tài liệu liên quan