Economic action and social structure the problem of embeddedness

31 1K 1
Economic action and social structure the problem of embeddedness

Đang tải... (xem toàn văn)

Tài liệu hạn chế xem trước, để xem đầy đủ mời bạn chọn Tải xuống

Thông tin tài liệu

Economic Action and Social Structure: The Problem of Embeddedness Author(s): Mark Granovetter Source: American Journal of Sociology, Vol 91, No (Nov., 1985), pp 481-510 Published by: The University of Chicago Press Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2780199 Accessed: 22/10/2014 05:15 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org The University of Chicago Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to American Journal of Sociology http://www.jstor.org This content downloaded from 121.33.190.134 on Wed, 22 Oct 2014 05:15:45 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Economic Action and Social Structure: The Problem of Embeddedness' Mark Granovetter State University of New York at Stony Brook How behavior and institutions are affected by social relations is one of the classic questions of social theory This paper concerns the extent to which economic action is embedded in structures of social relations, in modern industrial society Although the usual neoclassical accounts provide an "undersocialized" or atomized-actor explanation of such action, reformist economists who attempt to bring social structure back in so in the "oversocialized"way criticized by Dennis Wrong Under- and oversocialized accounts are paradoxically similar in their neglect of ongoing structures of social relations, and a sophisticated account of economic action must consider its embeddedness in such structures The argument is illustrated by a critique of Oliver Williamson's "markets and hierarchies"research program INTRODUCTION:THE PROBLEMOF EMBEDDEDNESS How behavior and institutions are affected by social relations is one of the classic questions of social theory Since such relations are always present, the situation that would arise in their absence can be imagined only through a thought experiment like Thomas Hobbes's "state of nature" or John Rawls's "original position." Much of the utilitarian tradition, including classical and neoclassical economics, assumes rational, selfinterested behavior affected minimally by social relations, thus invoking an idealized state not far from that of these thought experiments At the other extreme lies what I call the argument of "embeddedness":the argu1 Earlier drafts of this paper were written in sabbatical facilities kindly provided by the Institute for Advanced Study and Harvard University Financial support was providedin part by the institute, by a John Simon GuggenheimMemorialFoundation fellowship, and by NSF Science Faculty Professional Development grant SPI 8165055 Among those who have helped clarify the arguments are Wayne Baker, Michael Bernstein, Albert Hirschman, Ron Jepperson, Eric Leifer, Don McCloskey, CharlesPerrow,James Rule, Michael Schwartz, Theda Skocpol, and HarrisonWhite Requests for reprintsshould be sent to Mark Granovetter,Departmentof Sociology, State University of New York at Stony Brook, Stony Brook, New York 11794-4356 ? 1985 by The University of Chicago All rights reserved 0002-9602/86/9103-0001$01 50 AJS Volume 91 Number (November 1985): 481-510 This content downloaded from 121.33.190.134 on Wed, 22 Oct 2014 05:15:45 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 481 American Journal of Sociology ment that the behavior and institutions to be analyzed are so constrained by ongoing social relations that to construe them as independent is a grievous misunderstanding This article concerns the embeddedness of economic behavior It has long been the majority view among sociologists, anthropologists, political scientists, and historians that such behavior was heavily embedded in social relations in premarket societies but became much more autonomous with modernization This view sees the economy as an increasingly separate, differentiated sphere in modern society, with economic transactions defined no longer by the social or kinship obligations of those transacting but by rational calculations of individual gain It is sometimes further argued that the traditional situation is reversed: instead of economic life being submerged in social relations, these relations become an epiphenomenon of the market The embeddedness position is associated with the "substantivist" school in anthropology, identified especially with Karl Polanyi (1944; Polanyi, Arensberg, and Pearson 1957) and with the idea of "moral economy" in history and political science (Thompson 1971; Scott 1976) It has also some obvious relation to Marxist thought Few economists, however, have accepted this conception of a break in embeddedness with modernization; most of them assert instead that embeddedness in earlier societies was not substantially greater than the low level found in modern markets The tone was set by Adam Smith, who postulated a "certain propensity in human nature to truck, barter and exchange one thing for another" ([1776] 1979, book 1, chap 2) and assumed that since labor was the only factor of production in primitive society, goods must have exchanged in proportion to their labor costs-as in the general classical theory of exchange ([1776] 1979, book 1, chap 6) From the 1920s on, certain anthropologists took a similar position, which came to be called the "formalist" one: even in tribal societies, economic behavior was sufficiently independent of social relations for standard neoclassical analysis to be useful (Schneider 1974) This position has recently received a new infusion as economists and fellow travelers in history and political science have developed a new interest in the economic analysis of social institutions-much of which falls into what is called the "new institutional economics"-and have argued that behavior and institutions previously interpreted as embedded in earlier societies, as well as in our own, can be better understood as resulting from the pursuit of self-interest by rational, more or less atomized individuals (e.g., North and Thomas 1973; Williamson 1975; Popkin 1979) My own view diverges from both schools of thought I assert that the level of embeddedness of economic behavior is lower in nonmarket societies than is claimed by substantivists and development theorists, and it has changed less with "modernization" than they believe; but I argue 482 This content downloaded from 121.33.190.134 on Wed, 22 Oct 2014 05:15:45 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Embeddedness also that this level has always been and continues to be more substantial than is allowed for by formalists and economists I not attempt here to treat the issues posed by nonmarket societies I proceed instead by a theoretical elaboration of the concept of embeddedness, whose value is then illustrated with a problem from modern society, currently important in the new institutional economics: which transactions in modern capitalist society are carried out in the market, and which subsumed within hierarchically organized firms? This question has been raised to prominence by the "markets and hierarchies" program of research initiated by Oliver Williamson (1975) OVER-AND UNDERSOCIALIZEDCONCEPTIONSOF HUMAN ACTIONIN SOCIOLOGYAND ECONOMICS I begin by recalling Dennis Wrong's 1961 complaint about an "oversocialized conception of man in modern sociology"-a conception of people as overwhelmingly sensitive to the opinions of others and hence obedient to the dictates of consensually developed systems of norms and values, internalized through socialization, so that obedience is not perceived as a burden To the extent that such a conception was prominent in 1961, it resulted in large part from Talcott Parsons's recognition of the problem of order as posed by Hobbes and his own attempt to resolve it by transcending the atomized, undersocialized conception of man in the utilitarian tradition of which Hobbes was part (Parsons 1937, pp 89-94) Wrong approved the break with atomized utilitarianism and the emphasis on actors' embeddedness in social context-the crucial factor absent from Hobbes's thinking-but warned of exaggerating the degree of this embeddedness and the extent to which it might eliminate conflict: It is frequentlythe task of the sociologistto call attentionto the intensity with which men desireand strive for the good opinionof theirimmediate associatesin a varietyof situations,particularlythosewherereceivedtheoriesor ideologieshave undulyemphasizedothermotives Thus sociologists have shownthat factoryworkersare moresensitiveto the attitudesof their fellow workers than to purely.economic incentives It is certainly not my intentionto criticizethe findingsof such studies My objectionis that [a]lthoughsociologistshave criticizedpast effortsto singleout one fundamentalmotive in human conduct,the desireto achievea favorable self-imageby winning approvalfrom others frequentlyoccupiessuch a position in their own thinking [1961, pp 188-89] Classical and neoclassical economics operates, in contrast, with an atomized, undersocialized conception of human action, continuing in the utilitarian tradition The theoretical arguments disallow by hypothesis any impact of social structure and social relations on production, distribution, or consumption In competitive markets, no producer or consumer 483 This content downloaded from 121.33.190.134 on Wed, 22 Oct 2014 05:15:45 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions American Journal of Sociology noticeably influences aggregate supply or demand or, therefore, prices or other terms of trade As Albert Hirschman has noted, such idealized markets, involving as they "large numbers of price-taking anonymous buyers and sellers supplied with perfect information function without any prolonged human or social contact between the parties Under perfect competition there is no room for bargaining, negotiation, remonstration or mutual adjustment and the various operators that contract together need not enter into recurrent or continuing relationships as a result of which they would get to know each other well" (1982, p 1473) It has long been recognized that the idealized markets of perfect competition have survived intellectual attack in part because self-regulating economic structures are politically attractive to many Another reason for this survival, less clearly understood, is that the elimination of social relations from economic analysis removes the problem of order from the intellectual agenda, at least in the economic sphere In Hobbes's argument, disorder arises because conflict-free social and economic transactions depend on trust and the absence of malfeasance But these are unlikely when individuals are conceived to have neither social relationships nor institutional context-as in the "state of nature." Hobbes contains the difficulty by superimposing a structure of autocratic authority The solution of classical liberalism, and correspondingly of classical economics, is antithetical: repressive political structures are rendered unnecessary by competitive markets that make force or fraud unavailing Competition determines the terms of trade in a way that individual traders cannot manipulate If traders encounter complex or difficult relationships, characterized by mistrust or malfeasance, they can simply move on to the legion of other traders willing to business on market terms; social relations and their details thus become frictional matters In classical and neoclassical economics, therefore, the fact that actors may have social relations with one another has been treated, if at all, as a frictional drag that impedes competitive markets In a much-quoted line, Adam Smith complained that "people of the same trade seldom meet together, even for merriment and diversion, but the conversation ends in a conspiracy against the public, or in some contrivance to raise prices." His laissez-faire politics allowed few solutions to this problem, but he did suggest repeal of regulations requiring all those in the same trade to sign a public register; the public existence of such information "connects individuals who might never otherwise be known to one another and gives every man of the trade a direction where to find every other man of it." Noteworthy here is not the rather lame policy prescription but the recognition that social atomization is prerequisite to perfect competition (Smith [1776] 1979, pp 232-33) 484 This content downloaded from 121.33.190.134 on Wed, 22 Oct 2014 05:15:45 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Embeddedness More recent comments by economists on "social influences" construe these as processes in which actors acquire customs, habits, or norms that are followed mechanically and automatically, irrespective of their bearing on rational choice This view, close to Wrong's "oversocialized conception," is reflected in James Duesenberry's quip that "economics is all about how people make choices; sociology is all about how they don't have any choices to make" (1960, p 233) and in E H Phelps Brown's description of the "sociologists' approach to pay determination" as deriving from the assumption that people act in "certain ways because to so is customary, or an obligation, or the 'natural thing to do,' or right and proper, or just and fair" (1977, p 17) But despite the apparent contrast between under- and oversocialized views, we should note an irony of great theoretical importance: both have in common a conception of action and decision carried out by atomized actors In the undersocialized account, atomization results from narrow utilitarian pursuit of self-interest; in the oversocialized one, from the fact that behavioral patterns have been internalized and ongoing social relations thus have only peripheral effects on behavior That the internalized rules of behavior are social in origin does not differentiate this argument decisively from a utilitarian one, in which the source of utility functions is left open, leaving room for behavior guided entirely by consensually determined norms and values-as in the oversocialized view Under- and oversocialized resolutions of the problem of order thus merge in their atomization of actors from immediate social context This ironic merger is already visible in Hobbes's Leviathan, in which the unfortunate denizens of the state of nature, overwhelmed by the disorder consequent to their atomization, cheerfully surrender all their rights to an authoritarian power and subsequently behave in a docile and honorable manner; by the artifice of a social contract, they lurch directly from an undersocialized to an oversocialized state When modern economists attempt to take account of social influences, they typically represent them in the oversocialized manner represented in the quotations above In so doing, they reverse the judgment that social influences are frictional but sustain the conception of how such influences operate In the theory of segmented labor markets, for example, Michael Piore has argued that members of each labor market segment are characterized by different styles of decision making and that the making of decisions by rational choice, custom, or command in upper-primary, lower-primary, and secondary labor markets respectively corresponds to the origins of workers in middle-, working-, and lowerclass subcultures (Piore 1975) Similarly, Samuel Bowles and Herbert Gintis, in their account of the consequences of American education, argue that different social classes display different cognitive processes because 485 This content downloaded from 121.33.190.134 on Wed, 22 Oct 2014 05:15:45 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions American Journal of Sociology of differences in the education provided to each Those destined for lower-level jobs are trained to be dependable followers of rules, while those who will be channeled into elite positions attend "elite four-year colleges" that "emphasize social relationships conformable with the higher levels in the production hierarchy As they 'master' one type of behavioral regulation they are either allowed to progress to the next or are channeled into the corresponding level in the hierarchy of production" (Bowles and Gintis 1975, p 132) But these oversocialized conceptions of how society influences individual behavior are rather mechanical: once we know the individual's social class or labor market sector, everything else in behavior is automatic, since they are so well socialized Social influence here is an external force that, like the deists' God, sets things in motion and has no further effects-a force that insinuates itself into the minds and bodies of individuals (as in the movie Invasion of the Body Snatchers), altering their way of making decisions Once we know in just what way an individual has been affected, ongoing social relations and structures are irrelevant Social influences are all contained inside an individual's head, so, in actual decision situations, he or she can be atomized as any Homo economicus, though perhaps with different rules for decisions More sophisticated (and thus less oversocialized) analyses of cultural influences (e.g., Fine and Kleinman 1979; Cole 1979, chap 1) make it clear that culture is not a once-for-all influence but an ongoing process, continuously constructed and reconstructed during interaction It not only shapes its members but also is shaped by them, in part for their own strategic reasons Even when economists take social relationships seriously, as such diverse figures as Harvey Leibenstein (1976) and Gary Becker (1976), they invariably abstract away from the history of relations and their position with respect to other relations-what might be called the historical and structural embeddedness of relations The interpersonal ties described in their arguments are extremely stylized, average, "typical"devoid of specific content, history, or structural location Actors' behavior results from their named role positions and role sets; thus we have arguments on how workers and supervisors, husbands and wives, or criminals and law enforcers will interact with one another, but these relations are not assumed to have individualized content beyond that given by the named roles This procedure is exactly what structural sociologists have criticized in Parsonian sociology-the relegation of the specifics of individual relations to a minor role in the overall conceptual scheme, epiphenomenal in comparison with enduring structures of normative role prescriptions deriving from ultimate value orientations In economic models, this treatment of social relations has the paradoxical effect of preserving atomized decision making even when decisions are 486 This content downloaded from 121.33.190.134 on Wed, 22 Oct 2014 05:15:45 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Embeddedness seen to involve more than one individual Because the analyzed set of individuals-usually dyads, occasionally larger groups-is abstracted out of social context, it is atomized in its behavior from that of other groups and from the history of its own relations Atomization has not been eliminated, merely transferred to the dyadic or higher level of analysis Note the use of an oversocialized conception-that of actors behaving exclusively in accord with their prescribed roles-to implement an atomized, undersocialized view A fruitful analysis of human action requires us to avoid the atomization implicit in the theoretical extremes of under- and oversocialized conceptions Actors not behave or decide as atoms outside a social context, nor they adhere slavishly to a script written for them by the particular intersection of social categories that they happen to occupy Their attempts at purposive action are instead embedded in concrete, ongoing systems of social relations In the remainder of this article I illustrate how this view of embeddedness alters our theoretical and empirical approach to the study of economic behavior I first narrow the focus to the question of trust and malfeasance in economic life and then use the "markets and hierarchies" problem to illustrate the use of embeddedness ideas in analyzing this question.2 EMBEDDEDNESS,TRUST, AND MALFEASANCEIN ECONOMICLIFE Since about 1970, there has been a flurry of interest among economists in the previously neglected issues of trust and malfeasance Oliver Williamson has noted that real economic actors engage not merely in the pursuit of self-interest but also in "opportunism"-"self-interest seeking with guile; agents who are skilled at dissembling realize transactional advantages.3 Economic man is thus a more subtle and devious creature than the usual self-interest seeking assumption reveals" (1975, p 255) There are many parallels between what are referred to here as the "undersocialized" and "oversocialized" views of action and what Burt (1982, chap 9) calls the "atomistic" and "normative" approaches Similarly, the embeddedness approach proposed here as a middle ground between under- and oversocialized views has an obvious family resemblance to Burt's "structural" approach to action My distinctions and approach also differ from Burt's in many ways that cannot be quickly summarized; these can be best appreciated by comparison of this article with his useful summary (1982, chap 9) and with the formal models that implement his conception (1982, 1983) Another approach that resembles mine in its emphasis on how social connections affect purposive action is Marsden's extension of James Coleman's theories of collective action and decision to situations where such connections modify results that would occur in a purely atomistic situation (Marsden 1981, 1983) 3Students of the sociology of sport will note that this proposition had been put forward previously, in slightly different form, by Leo Durocher 487 This content downloaded from 121.33.190.134 on Wed, 22 Oct 2014 05:15:45 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions American Journal of Sociology But this points out a peculiar assumption of modern economic theory, that one's economic interest is pursued only by comparatively gentlemanly means The Hobbesian question-how it can be that those who pursue their own interest not so mainly by force and fraud-is finessed by this conception Yet, as Hobbes saw so clearly, there is nothing in the intrinsic meaning of "self-interest"that excludes force or fraud In part, this assumption persisted because competitive forces, in a selfregulating market, could be imagined to suppress force and fraud But the idea is also embedded in the intellectual history of the discipline In The Passions and the Interests, Albert Hirschman (1977) shows that an important strand of intellectual history from the time of Leviathan to that of The Wealth of Nations consisted of the watering down of Hobbes's problem of order by arguing that certain human motivations kept others under control and that, in particular, the pursuit of economic self-interest was typically not an uncontrollable "passion"but a civilized, gentle activity The wide though implicit acceptance of such an idea is a powerful example of how under- and oversocialized conceptions complement one another: atomized actors in competitive markets so thoroughly internalize these normative standards of behavior as to guarantee orderly transactions.4 What has eroded this confidence in recent years has been increased attention to the micro-level details of imperfectly competitive markets, characterized by small numbers of participants with sunk costs and "specific human capital" investments In such situations, the alleged discipline of competitive markets cannot be called on to mitigate deceit, so the classical problem of how it can be that daily economic life is not riddled with mistrust and malfeasance has resurfaced In the economic literature, I see two fundamental answers to this problem and argue that one is linked to an undersocialized, and the other to an oversocialized, conception of human action The undersocialized account is found mainly in the new institutional economics-a loosely defined confederation of economists with an interest in explaining social institutions from a neoclassical viewpoint (See, e.g., Furubotn and Pejovich 1972; Alchian and Demsetz 1973; Lazear 1979; Rosen 1982; Williamson 1975, 1979, 1981; Williamson and Ouchi 1981.) The general story told by members of this school is that social institutions and arrangements previously thought to be the adventitious result of legal, historical, social, or political forces are better viewed as the efficient solution to certain economic problems The tone is similar to that of structural-functional sociology of the 1940s to the 1960s, and much of the argumentation fails the elementary tests of a sound functional explanation laid down by I am indebted to an anonymous referee for pointing this out 488 This content downloaded from 121.33.190.134 on Wed, 22 Oct 2014 05:15:45 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Embeddedness Robert Merton in 1947 Consider, for example, Schotter's view that to understand any observed economic institution requires only that we "infer the evolutionary problem that must have existed for the institution as we see it to have developed Every evolutionary economic problem requires a social institution to solve it" (1981, p 2) Malfeasance is here seen to be averted because clever institutional arrangements make it too costly to engage in, and these arrangementsmany previously interpreted as serving no economic function-are now seen as having evolved to discourage malfeasance Note, however, that they not produce trust but instead are a functional substitute for it The main such arrangements are elaborate explicit and implicit contracts (Okun 1981), including deferred compensation plans and mandatory retirement-seen to reduce the incentives for "shirking"on the job or absconding with proprietary secrets (Lazear 1979; Pakes and Nitzan 1982)-and authority structures that deflect opportunism by making potentially divisive decisions by fiat (Williamson 1975) These conceptions are undersocialized in that they not allow for the extent to which concrete personal relations and the obligations inherent in them discourage malfeasance, quite apart from institutional arrangements Substituting these arrangements for trust results actually in a Hobbesian situation, in which any rational individual would be motivated to develop clever ways to evade them; it is then hard to imagine that everyday economic life would not be poisoned by ever more ingenious attempts at deceit Other economists have recognized that some degree of trust must be assumed to operate, since institutional arrangements alone could not entirely stem force or fraud But it remains to explain the source of this trust, and appeal is sometimes made to the existence of a "generalized morality." Kenneth Arrow, for example, suggests that societies, "in their evolution have developed implicit agreements to certain kinds of regard for others, agreements which are essential to the survival of the society or at least contribute greatly to the efficiency of its working" (1974, p 26; see also Akerlof [1983] on the origins of "honesty") Now one can hardly doubt the existence of some such generalized morality; without it, you would be afraid to give the gas station attendant a 20-dollar bill when you had bought only five dollars' worth of gas But this conception has the oversocialized characteristic of calling on a generalized and automatic response, even though moral action in economic life is hardly automatic or universal (as is well known at gas stations that demand exact change after dark) Consider a case where generalized morality does indeed seem to be at work: the legendary (I hesitate to say apocryphal) economist who, against all economic rationality, leaves a tip in a roadside restaurant far from home Note that this transaction has three characteristics that make it 489 This content downloaded from 121.33.190.134 on Wed, 22 Oct 2014 05:15:45 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions American Journal of Sociology cially among business elites, is one of the best-documented facts in the sociological study of business (e.g., Domhoff 1971; Useem 1979) In his study of the extent to which litigation was used to settle disputes between firms, Macaulay notes that disputes are "frequently settled without reference to the contract or potential or actual legal sanctions There is a hesitancy to speak of legal rights or to threaten to sue in these negotiations Or as one businessman put it, 'You can settle any dispute if you keep the lawyers and accountants out of it They just not understand the give-and-take needed in business.' Law suits for breach of contract appear to be rare" (1963, p 61) He goes on to explain that the top executivesof the two firmsmayknoweachother.Theymaysit together on governmentor trade committees.They may know each other socially and even belongto the samecountryclub Even whereagreementcan be reachedat the negotiationstage, carefullyplannedarrangementsmay create undesirableexchangerelationshipsbetween business units Some businessmenobjectthatin sucha carefullyworkedout relationshipone gets performanceonly to the letter of the contract.Such planningindicatesa lack of trust and blunts the demandsof friendship,turninga cooperative ventureinto an antagonistichorsetrade Threateningto turnmatters over to an attorneymay cost no moremoneythan postageor a telephone call;yet few are so skilledin makingsucha threatthat it will not cost some deteriorationof the relationshipbetweenthe firms.[Pp 63-64] It is not only at top levels that firms are connected by networks of personal relations, but at all levels where transactions must take place It is, for example, a commonplace in the literature on industrial purchasing that buying and selling relationships rarely approximate the spot-market model of classical theory One source indicates that the "evidence consistently suggests that it takes some kind of 'shock' to jolt the organizational buying out of a pattern of placing repeat orders with a favored supplier or to extend the constrained set of feasible suppliers A moment's reflection will suggest several reasons for this behavior, including the costs associated with searching for new suppliers and establishing new relationships, the fact that users are likely to prefer sources, the relatively low risk involved in dealing with known vendors, and the likelihood that the buyer has established personal relationships that he values with representatives of the supplying firm" (Webster and Wind 1972, p 15) In a similar vein, Macaulay notes that salesmen "often know purchasing agents well The same two individuals may have dealt with each other from five to 25 years Each has something to give the other Salesmen have gossip about competitors, shortages and price increases to give purchasing agents who treat them well" (1963, p 63) Sellers who not satisfy their customers "become the subject of discussion in the gossip exchanged by purchasing agents and salesmen, at meetings of purchasing agents' associations and trade associations or even at country clubs or 496 This content downloaded from 121.33.190.134 on Wed, 22 Oct 2014 05:15:45 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Embeddedness social gatherings " (p 64) Settlement of disputes is eased by this embeddedness of business in social relations: "Even where the parties have a detailed and carefully planned agreement which indicates what is to happen if, say, the seller fails to deliver on time, often they will never refer to the agreement but will negotiate a solution when the problem arises as if there never had been any original contract One purchasing agent expressed a common business attitude when he said, 'If something comes up, you get the other man on the telephone and deal with the problem You don't read legalistic contract clauses at each other if you ever want to business again One doesn't run to lawyers if he wants to stay in business because one must behave decently"' (Macaulay 1963, p 61) Such patterns may be more easily noted in other countries, where they are supposedly explained by "cultural"peculiarities Thus, one journalist recently asserted, Friendshipsand longstandingpersonalconnectionsaffectbusinessconnections everywhere.But that seems to be especiallytrue in Japan The after-hourssessionsin the barsand nightclubsare wherethe vital personal contactsare establishedand nurturedslowly Oncethese ties are set, they are not easily undone The resultingtight-knitnature of Japanese businesssocietyhas long been a sourceof frustrationto foreigncompanies tryingto sell productsin Japan ChalmersJohnson,a professorat Berkeley,believesthat the exclusivedealingwithintheJapaneseindustrial groups,buyingand sellingto and fromeach otherbased on decadesold relationshipsratherthan economiccompetitiveness is a real nontariffbarrier[to trade between the United States and Japan] [bohr 1982] The extensive use of subcontracting in many industries also presents opportunities for sustained relationships among firms that are not organized hierarchically within one corporate unit For example, Eccles cites evidence from many countries that in construction, when projects "are not subject to institutional regulations which require competitive bidding relations between the general contractor and his subcontractors are stable and continuous over fairly long periods of time and only infrequently established through competitive bidding This type of 'quasiintegration' results in what I call the 'quasifirm.' It is a preferred mode to either pure market transactions or formal vertical integration" (1981, pp 339-40) Eccles describes this "quasifirm"arrangement of extensive and long-term relationships among contractors and subcontractors as an organizational form logically intermediate between the pure market and the vertically integrated firm I would argue, however, that it is not empirically intermediate, since the former situation is so rare The case of construction is closer to vertical integration than some other situations where firms interact, such as buying and selling relations, since subcon497 This content downloaded from 121.33.190.134 on Wed, 22 Oct 2014 05:15:45 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions American Journal of Sociology tractors are physically located on the same site as the contractor and are under his general supervision Furthermore, under the usual fixed-price contracts, there are "obvious incentives for shirking performance requirements" (Eccles 1981, p 340) Yet a hierarchical structure associated with the vertically integrated firm does not arise to meet this "problem." I argue this is because the long-term relations of contractors and subcontractors, as well as the embeddedness of those relations in a community of construction personnel, generate standards of expected behavior that not only obviate the need for but are superior to pure authority relations in discouraging malfeasance Eccles's own empirical study of residential construction in Massachusetts shows not only that subcontracting relationships are long term in nature but also that it is very rare for a general contractor to employ more than two or three subcontractors in a given trade, whatever number of projects is handled in the course of a year (1981, pp 349-5 1) This is true despite the availability of large numbers of alternative subcontractors This phenomenon can be explained in part in investment terms-through a "continuing association both parties can benefit from the somewhat idiosyncratic investment of learning to work together" (Eccles 1981, p 340)-but also must be related to the desire of individuals to derive pleasure from the social interaction that accompanies their daily work, a pleasure that would be considerably blunted by spot-market procedures requiring entirely new and strange work partners each day As in other parts of economic life, the overlay of social relations on what may begin in purely economic transactions plays a crucial role Some comments on labor markets are also relevant here One advantage that Williamson asserts for hierarchically structured firms over market transactions is the ability to transmit accurate information about employees "The principal impediment to effective interfirm experiencerating," he argues, "is one of communication By comparison with the firm, markets lack a rich and common rating language The language problem is particularly severe where the judgments to be made are highly subjective The advantages of hierarchy in these circumstances are especially great if those persons who are most familiar with a worker's characteristics, usually his immediate supervisor, also the experience-rating" (1975, p 78) But the notion that good information about the characteristics of an employee can be transmitted only within firms and not between can be sustained only by neglecting the widely variegated social network of interaction that spans firms Information about employees travels among firms not only because personal relations exist between those in each firm who business with each other but also, as I have shown in detail (Granovetter 1974), because the relatively high levels of interfirm mobility in the United States guarantee that many workers will be reason498 This content downloaded from 121.33.190.134 on Wed, 22 Oct 2014 05:15:45 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Embeddedness ably well known to employees of numerous other firms that might require and solicit their services Furthermore, the idea that internal information is necessarily accurate and acted on dispassionately by promotion procedures keyed to it seems naive To say, as Williamson does, that reliance "on internal promotion has affirmative incentive properties because workers can anticipate that differential talent and degrees of cooperativeness will be rewarded" (1975, p 78) invokes an ideal type of promotion as reward-for-achievement that can readily be shown to have only limited correspondence to existing internal labor markets (see Granovetter 1983, pp 40-51, for an extended analysis) The other side of my critique is to argue that Williamson vastly overestimates the efficacy of hierarchical power ("fiat," in his terminology) within organizations He asserts, for example, that internal organizations have a great auditing advantage: "An external auditor is typically constrained to review written records An internal auditor, by contrast, has greater freedom of action Whereas an internal auditor is not a partisan but regards himself and is regarded by others in mainly instrumental terms, the external auditor is associated with the 'other side' and his motives are regarded suspiciously The degree of cooperation received by the auditor from the audited party varies accordingly The external auditor can expect to receive only perfunctory cooperation" (1975, pp 29-30) The literature on intrafirm audits is sparse, but one thorough account is that of Dalton, in Men Who Manage, for a large chemical plant Audits of parts by the central office were supposed to be conducted on a surprise basis, but warning was typically surreptitiously given The high level of cooperation shown in these internal audits is suggested by the following account: "Notice that a count of parts was to begin provoked a flurry among the executives to hide certain parts and equipment materials not to be counted were moved to: 1) little-known and inaccessible spots; 2) basements and pits that were dirty and therefore unlikely to be examined; 3) departments that had already been inspected and that could be approached circuitously while the counters were en route between official storage areas and 4) places where materials and supplies might be used as a camouflage for parts As the practice developed, cooperation among the [department] chiefs to use each other's storage areas and available pits became well organized and smoothly functioning" (Dalton 1959, pp 48-49) Dalton's work shows brilliantly that cost accounting of all kinds is a highly arbitrary and therefore easily politicized process rather than a technical procedure decided on grounds of efficiency He details this especially for the relationship between the maintenance department and various production departments in the chemical plant; the department to which maintenance work was charged had less to with any strict time 499 This content downloaded from 121.33.190.134 on Wed, 22 Oct 2014 05:15:45 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions American Journal of Sociology accounting than with the relative political and social standing of department executives in their relation to maintenance personnel Furthermore, the more aggressive department heads expedited their maintenance work "by the use of friendships, by bullying and implied threats As all the heads had the same formal rank, one could say that an inverse relation existed between a given officer's personal influence and his volume of uncompleted repairs" (1959, p 34) Questioned about how such practices could escape the attention of auditors, one informant told Dalton, "If Auditing got to snooping around, what the hell could they find out? And if they did find anything, they'd know a damn sight better than to say anything about it All those guys [department heads] have got lines through Cost Accounting That's a lot of bunk about Auditing being independent" (p 32) Accounts as detailed and perceptive as Dalton's are sadly lacking for a representative sample of firms and so are open to the argument that they are exceptional But similar points can be made for the problem of transfer pricing-the determination of prices for products traded between divisions of a single firm Here Williamson argues that though the trading divisions "may have profit-center standing, this is apt to be exercised in a restrained way Cost-plus pricing rules, and variants thereof, preclude supplier divisions from seeking the monopolistic prices [to] which their sole source supply position might otherwise entitle them In addition, the managements of the trading divisions are more susceptible to appeals for cooperation" (1975, p 29) But in an intensive empirical study of transfer-pricing practices, Eccles, having interviewed nearly 150 managers in 13 companies, concluded that no cost-based methods could be carried out in a technically neutral way, since there is "no universal criterion for what is cost Problems often exist with cost-based methods when the buying division does not have access to the information by which the costs are generated Market prices are especially difficult to determine when internal purchasing is mandated and no external purchases are made of the intermediate good There is no obvious answer to what is a markup for profit " (1982, p 21) The political element in transfer-pricing conflicts strongly affects whose definition of "cost"is accepted: "In general, when transfer pricing practices are seen to enhance one's power and status they will be viewed favorably When they not, a countless number of strategic and other sound business reasons will be found to argue for their inadequacy" (1982, p 21; see also Eccles 1983, esp pp 26-32) Eccles notes the "somewhat ironic fact that many managers consider internal transactions to be more difficult than external ones, even though vertical integration is pursued for presumed advantages" (1983, p 28) Thus, the oversocialized view that orders within a hierarchy elicit easy 500 This content downloaded from 121.33.190.134 on Wed, 22 Oct 2014 05:15:45 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Embeddedness obedience and that employees internalize the interests of the firm, suppressing any conflict with their own, cannot stand scrutiny against these empirical studies (or, for that matter, against the experience of many of us in actual organizations) Note further that, as shown especially well in Dalton's detailed ethnographic study, resistance to the encroachment of organizational interests on personal or divisional ones requires an extensive network of coalitions From the viewpoint of management, these coalitions represent malfeasance generated by teams; it could not be managed at all by atomized individuals Indeed, Dalton asserted that the level of cooperation achieved by divisional chiefs in evading central audits involved joint action "of a kind rarely, if ever, shown in carrying on official activities " (1959, p 49) In addition, the generally lower turnover of personnel characteristic of large hierarchical firms, with their well-defined internal labor markets and elaborate promotion ladders, may make such cooperative evasion more likely When many employees have long tenures, the conditions are met for a dense and stable network of relations, shared understandings, and political coalitions to be constructed (See Homans 1950, 1974, for the relevant social psychological discussions; and Pfeffer 1983, for a treatment of the "demography of organizations.") James Lincoln notes, in this connection, that in the ideal-typical Weberian bureaucracy, organizations are "designed to function independently of the collective actions which can be mobilized through [internal] interpersonal networks Bureaucracy prescribes fixed relationships among positions through which incumbents flow, without, in theory, affecting organizational operations" (1982, p 26) He goes on to summarize studies showing, however, that "when turnover is low, relations take on additional contents of an expressive and personal sort which may ultimately transform the network and change the directions of the organization" (p 26) To this point I have argued that social relations between firms are more important, and authority within firms less so, in bringing order to economic life than is supposed in the markets and hierarchies line of thought A balanced and symmetrical argument requires attention to power in "market" relations and social connections within firms Attention to power relations is needed lest my emphasis on the smoothing role of social relations in the market lead me to neglect the role of these relations in the conduct of conflict Conflict is an obvious reality, ranging from wellpublicized litigation between firms to the occasional cases of "cutthroat competition" gleefully reported by the business press Since the effective exercise of power between firms will prevent bloody public battles, we can assume that such battles represent only a small proportion of actual conflicts of interest Conflicts probably become public only when the two sides are fairly equally matched; recall that this rough equality was pre501 This content downloaded from 121.33.190.134 on Wed, 22 Oct 2014 05:15:45 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions American Journal of Sociology cisely one of Hobbes's arguments for a probable "war of all against all" in the "state of nature." But when the power position of one firm is obviously dominant, the other is apt to capitulate early so as to cut its losses Such capitulation may require not even explicit confrontation but only a clear understanding of what the other side requires (as in the recent Marxist literature on "hegemony" in business life; see, e.g., Mintz and Schwartz 1985) Though the exact extent to which firms dominate other firms can be debated, the voluminous literature on interlocking directorates, on the role of financial institutions vis-a-vis industrial corporations, and on dual economy surely provides enough evidence to conclude that power relations cannot be neglected This provides still another reason to doubt that the complexities that arise when formally equal agents negotiate with one another can be resolved only by the subsumption of all parties under a single hierarchy; in fact, many of these complexities are resolved by implicit or explicit power relations among firms Finally, a brief comment is in order on the webs of social relations that are well known from industrial and organizational sociology to be important within firms The distinction between the "formal" and the "informal" organization of the firm is one of the oldest in the literature, and it hardly needs repeating that observers who assume firms to be structured in fact by the official organization chart are sociological babes in the woods The connection of this to the present discussion is that insofar as internalization within firms does result in a better handling of complex and idiosyncratic transactions, it is by no means apparent that hierarchical organization is the best explanation It may be, instead, that the effect of internalization is to provide a focus (see Feld 1981) for an even denser web of social relations than had occurred between previously independent market entities Perhaps this web of interaction is mainly what explains the level of efficiency, be it high or low, of the new organizational form It is now useful to summarize the differences in explanation and prediction between Williamson's markets and hierarchies approach and the embeddedness view offered here Williamson explains the inhibition of "'opportunism"or malfeasance in economic life and the general existence of cooperation and order by the subsumption of complex economic activity in hierarchically integrated firms The empirical evidence that I cite shows, rather, that even with complex transactions, a high level of order can often be found in the "market"-that is, across firm boundaries-and a correspondingly high level of disorder within the firm Whether these occur, instead of what Williamson expects, depends on the nature of personal relations and networks of relations between and within firms I claim that both order and disorder, honesty and malfeasance have more 502 This content downloaded from 121.33.190.134 on Wed, 22 Oct 2014 05:15:45 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Embeddedness to with structures of such relations than they with organizational form Certain implications follow for the conditions under which one may expect to see vertical integration rather than transactions between firms in a market Other things being equal, for example, we should expect pressures toward vertical integration in a market where transacting firms lack a network of personal relations that connects them or where such a network eventuates in conflict, disorder, opportunism, or malfeasance On the other hand, where a stable network of relations mediates complex transactions and generates standards of behavior between firms, such pressures should be absent I use the word "pressures"rather than predict that vertical integration will always follow the pattern described in order to avoid the functionalism implicit in Williamson's assumption that whatever organizational form is most efficient will be the one observed Before we can make this assumption, two further conditions must be satisfied: (i) well-defined and powerful selection pressures toward efficiency must be operating, and (ii) some actors must have the ability and resources to "solve" the efficiency problem by constructing a vertically integrated firm The selection pressures that guarantee efficient organization of transactions are nowhere clearly described by Williamson As in much of the new institutional economics, the need to make such matters explicit is obviated by an implicit Darwinian argument that efficient solutions, however they may originate, have a staying power akin to that enforced by natural selection in the biological world Thus it is granted that not all business executives "accurately perceive their business opportunities and faultlessly respond Over time, however, those [vertical] integration moves that have better rationality properties (in transaction cost and scale-economy terms) tend to have better survival properties" (Williamson and Ouchi 1981, p 389; see also Williamson 1981, pp 573-74) But Darwinian arguments, invoked in this cavalier fashion, careen toward a Panglossian view of whatever institution is analyzed The operation of alleged selection pressures is here neither an object of study nor even a falsifiable proposition but rather an article of faith Even if one could document selection pressures that made survival of certain organizational forms more likely, it would remain to show how such forms could be implemented To treat them implicitly as mutations, by analogy to biological evolution, merely evades the issue As in other functionalist explanations, it cannot be automatically assumed that the solution to some problem is feasible Among the resources required to implement vertical integration might be some measure of market power, access to capital through retained earnings or capital markets, and appropriate connections to legal or regulatory authorities 503 This content downloaded from 121.33.190.134 on Wed, 22 Oct 2014 05:15:45 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions American Journal of Sociology Where selection pressures are weak (especially likely in the imperfect markets claimed by Williamson to produce vertical integration) and resources problematic, the social-structural configurations that I have outlined are still related to the efficiency of transaction costs, but no guarantee can be given that an efficient solution will occur Motives for integration unrelated to efficiency, such as personal aggrandizement of CEOs in acquiring firms, may in such settings become important What the viewpoint proposed here requires is that future research on the markets-hierarchies question pay careful and systematic attention to the actual patterns of personal relations by which economic transactions are carried out Such attention will not only better sort out the motives for vertical integration but also make it easier to comprehend the various complex intermediate forms between idealized atomized markets and completely integrated firms, such as the quasi firm discussed above for the construction industry Intermediate forms of this kind are so intimately bound up with networks of personal relations that any perspective that considers these relations peripheral will fail to see clearly what "organizational form" has been effected Existing empirical studies of industrial organization pay little attention to patterns of relations, in part because relevant data are harder to find than those on technology and market structure but also because the dominant economic framework remains one of atomized actors, so personal relations are perceived as frictional in effect DISCUSSION In this article, I have argued that most behavior is closely embedded in networks of interpersonal relations and that such an argument avoids the extremes of under- and oversocialized views of human action Though I believe this to be so for all behavior, I concentrate here on economic behavior for two reasons: (i) it is the type-case of behavior inadequately interpreted because those who study it professionally are so strongly committed to atomized theories of action; and (ii) with few exceptions, sociologists have refrained from serious study of any subject already claimed by neoclassical economics They have implicitly accepted the presumption of economists that "market processes" are not suitable objects of sociological study because social relations play only a frictional and disruptive role, not a central one, in modern societies (Recent exceptions are Baker 1983; Burt 1983; and White 1981.) In those instances in which sociologists study processes where markets are central, they usually still manage to avoid their analysis Until recently, for example, the large sociological literature on wages was cast in terms of "income attainment," obscuring the labor 504 This content downloaded from 121.33.190.134 on Wed, 22 Oct 2014 05:15:45 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Embeddedness market context in which wages are set and focusing instead on the background and attainment of individuals (see Granovetter 1981 for an extended critique) Or, as Stearns has pointed out, the literature on who controls corporations has implicitly assumed that analysis must be at the level of political relations and broad assumptions about the nature of capitalism Even though it is widely admitted that how corporations acquire capital is a major determinant of control, most relevant research "since the turn of the century has eliminated that [capital] market as an objective of investigation" (1982, pp 5-6) Even in organization theory, where considerable literature implements the limits placed on economic decisions by social structural complexity, little attempt has been made to demonstrate the implications of this for the neoclassical theory of the firm or for a general understanding of production or such macroeconomic outcomes as growth, inflation, and unemployment In trying to demonstrate that all market processes are amenable to sociological analysis and that such analysis reveals central, not peripheral, features of these processes, I have narrowed my focus to problems of trust and malfeasance I have also used the "market and hierarchies" argument of Oliver Williamson as an illustration of how the embeddedness perspective generates different understandings and predictions from that implemented by economists Williamson's perspective is itself "revisionist"within economics, diverging from the neglect of institutional and transactional considerations typical of neoclassical work In this sense, it may appear to have more kinship to a sociological perspective than the usual economic arguments But the main thrust of the "new institutional economists" is to deflect the analysis of institutions from sociological, historical, and legal argumentation and show instead that they arise as the efficient solution to economic problems This mission and the pervasive functionalism it implies discourage the detailed analysis of social structure that I argue here is the key to understanding how existing institutions arrived at their present state Insofar as rational choice arguments are narrowly construed as referring to atomized individuals and economic goals, they are inconsistent with the embeddedness position presented here In a broader formulation of rational choice, however, the two views have much in common Much of the revisionist work by economists that I criticize above in my discussion of over- and undersocialized conceptions of action relies on a strategy that might be called "psychological revisionism"-an attempt to reform economic theory by abandoning an absolute assumption of rational decision making This strategy has led to Leibenstein's "selective rationality" in his arguments on "X-inefficiency" (1976), for example, and to the claims of segmented labor-market theorists that workers in different mar- 505 This content downloaded from 121.33.190.134 on Wed, 22 Oct 2014 05:15:45 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions American Journal of Sociology ket segments have different kinds of decision-making rules, rational choice being only for upper-primary (i.e., professional, managerial, technical) workers (Piore 1979) I suggest, in contrast, that while the assumption of rational action must always be problematic, it is a good working hypothesis that should not easily be abandoned What looks to the analyst like nonrational behavior may be quite sensible when situational constraints, especially those of embeddedness, are fully appreciated When the social situation of those in nonprofessional labor markets is fully analyzed, their behavior looks less like the automatic application of "cultural" rules and more like a reasonable response to their present situation (as, e.g., in the discussion of Liebow 1966) Managers who evade audits and fight over transfer pricing are acting nonrationally in some strict economic sense, in terms of a firm's profit maximization; but when their position and ambitions in intrafirm networks and political coalitions are analyzed, the behavior is easily interpreted That such behavior is rational or instrumental is more readily seen, moreover, if we note that it aims not only at economic goals but also at sociability, approval, status, and power Economists rarely see such goals as rational, in part on account of the arbitrary separation that arose historically, as Albert Hirschman (1977) points out, in the 17th and 18th centuries, between the "passions"and the "interests,"the latter connoting economic motives only This way of putting the matter has led economists to specialize in analysis of behavior motivated only by "interest"and to assume that other motives occur in separate and nonrationally organized spheres; hence Samuelson's much-quoted comment that "many economists would separate economics from sociology upon the basis of rational or irrational behavior" (1947, p 90) The notion that rational choice is derailed by social influences has long discouraged detailed sociological analysis of economic life and led revisionist economists to reform economic theory by focusing on its naive psychology My claim here is that however naive that psychology may be, this is not where the main difficulty lies-it is rather in the neglect of social structure Finally, I should add that the level of causal analysis adopted in the embeddedness argument is a rather proximate one I have had little to say about what broad historical or macrostructural circumstances have led systems to display the social-structural characteristics they have, so I make no claims for this analysis to answer large-scale questions about the nature of modern society or the sources of economic and political change But the focus on proximate causes is intentional, for these broader questions cannot be satisfactorily addressed without more detailed understanding of the mechanisms by which sweeping change has its effects My claim is that one of the most important and least analyzed of such mecha506 This content downloaded from 121.33.190.134 on Wed, 22 Oct 2014 05:15:45 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Embeddedness nisms is the impact of such change on the social relations in which economic life is embedded If this is so, no adequate link between macro- and micro-level theories can be established without a much fuller understanding of these relations The use of embeddedness analysis in explicating proximate causes of patterns of macro-level interest is well illustrated by the markets and hierarchies question The extent of vertical integration and the reasons for the persistence of small firms operating through the market are not only narrow concerns of industrial organization; they are of interest to all students of the institutions of advanced capitalism Similar issues arise in the analysis of "dual economy," dependent development, and the nature of modern corporate elites But whether small firms are indeed eclipsed by giant corporations is usually analyzed in broad and sweeping macropolitical or macroeconomic terms, with little appreciation of proximate social structural causes Analysts of dual economy have often suggested, for example, that the persistence of large numbers of small firms in the "periphery"is explained by large corporations' need to shift the risks of cyclical fluctuations in demand or of uncertain R & D activities; failures of these small units will not adversely affect the larger firms' earnings I suggest here that small firms in a market setting may persist instead because a dense network of social relations is overlaid on the business relations connecting such firms and reduces pressures for integration This does not rule out risk shifting as an explanation with a certain face validity But the embeddedness account may be more useful in explaining the large number of small establishments not characterized by satellite or peripheral status (For a discussion of the surprising extent of employment in small establishments, see Granovetter 1984.) This account is restricted to proximate causes: it logically leads to but does not answer the questions why, when, and in what sectors does the market display various types of social structure But those questions, which link to a more macro level of analysis, would themselves not arise without a prior appreciation of the importance of social structure in the market The markets and hierarchies analysis, important as it may be, is presented here mainly as an illustration I believe the embeddedness argument to have very general applicability and to demonstrate not only that there is a place for sociologists in the study of economic life but that their perspective is urgently required there In avoiding the analysis of phenomena at the center of standard economic theory, sociologists have unnecessarily cut themselves off from a large and important aspect of social life and from the European tradition-stemming especially from Max Weber-in which economic action is seen only as a special, if important, category of social action I hope to have shown here that this Weberian 507 This content downloaded from 121.33.190.134 on Wed, 22 Oct 2014 05:15:45 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions American Journal of Sociology program is consistent with and furthered by some of the insights of modern structural sociology REFERENCES Akerlof, George 1983 "Loyalty Filters." American Economic Review 73 (1): 54-63 Alchian, Armen, and Harold Demsetz 1973 "The Property Rights Paradigm." Journal of Economic History 33 (March): 16-27 Arrow, Kenneth 1974 The Limits of Organization New York: Norton Baker, Wayne 1983 "Floor Trading and Crowd Dynamics." In Social Dynamics of Financial Markets, edited by Patricia Adler and Peter Adler Greenwich, Conn.: JAI Becker, Gary 1976 The Economic Approach to Human Behavior Chicago: University of Chicago Press Ben-Porath, Yoram 1980 "The F-Connection: Families, Friends and Firms in the Organization of Exchange." Population and Development Review (1): 1-30 Bowles, Samuel, and Herbert Gintis 1975 Schooling in Capitalist America New York: Basic Brown, Roger 1965 Social Psychology New York: Free Press Burt, Ronald 1982 Toward a Structural Theory of Action New York: Academic Press 1983 Corporate Profits and Cooptation New York: Academic Press Cole, Robert 1979 Work, Mobility and Participation: A Comparative Study of American and Japanese Industry Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press Dalton, Melville 1959 Men Who Manage New York: Wiley Doeringer, Peter, and Michael Piore 1971 Internal Labor Markets and Manpower Analysis Lexington, Mass.: Heath Domhoff, G William 1971 The Higher Circles New York: Random House Duesenberry, James 1960 Comment on "An Economic Analysis of Fertility." In Demographic and Economic Change in Developed Countries, edited by the Universities-National Bureau Committee for Economic Research Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press Eccles, Robert 1981 "The Quasifirm in the' Construction Industry." Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization (December): 335-57 1982 "A Synopsis of Transfer Pricing: An Analysis and Action Plan." Mimeographed Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard Business School .1983 "Transfer Pricing, Fairness and Control." Working Paper no HBS 83167 Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard Business School Reprinted in Harvard Business Review (in press) Feld, Scott 1981 "The Focused Organization of Social Ties." American Journal of Sociology 86 (5): 1015-35 Fine, Gary, and Sherryl Kleinman 1979 "Rethinking Subculture: An Interactionist Analysis." American Journal of Sociology 85 (July): 1-20 Furubotn, E., and S Pejovich 1972 "Property Rights and Economic Theory: A Survey of Recent Literature." Journal of Economic Literature 10 (3): 1137-62 Geertz, Clifford 1979 "Suq: The Bazaar Economy in Sefrou." Pp 123-225 in Meaning and Order in Moroccan Society, edited by C Geertz, H Geertz, and L Rosen New York: Cambridge University Press Granovetter, Mark 1974 Getting a Job: A Study of Contacts and Careers Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press 1981 "Toward a Sociological Theory of Income Differences." Pp 11-47 in Sociological Perspectives on Labor Markets, edited by Ivar Berg New York: Academic Press 508 This content downloaded from 121.33.190.134 on Wed, 22 Oct 2014 05:15:45 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions Embeddedness 1983 "Labor Mobility, Internal Markets and Job-Matching: A Comparison of the Sociological and Economic Approaches." Mimeographed 1984 "Small Is Bountiful: Labor Markets and Establishment Size." American Sociological Review 49 (3): 323-34 Hirschman, Albert 1977 The Passions and the Interests Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press 1982 "Rival Interpretations of Market Society: Civilizing, Destructive or Feeble?" Journal of Economic Literature 20 (4): 1463-84 Homans, George 1950 The Human Group New York: Harcourt Brace & Co 1974 Social Behavior New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich Lazear, Edward 1979 "Why Is There Mandatory Retirement?" Journal of Political Economy 87 (6): 1261-84 Leibenstein, Harvey 1976 Beyond Economic Man Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press Liebow, Elliot 1966 Tally's Corner Boston: Little, Brown Lincoln, James 1982 "Intra- (and Inter-) Organizational Networks." Pp 1-38 in Research in the Sociology of Organizations, vol Edited by S Bacharach Greenwich, Conn.: JAI Lohr, Steve 1982 "When Money Doesn't Matter in Japan." New York Times (December 30) Macaulay, Stewart 1963 "Non-Contractual Relations in Business: A Preliminary Study." American Sociological Review 28 (1): 55-67 Marsden, Peter 1981 "Introducing Influence Processes into a System of Collective Decisions." American Journal of Sociology 86 (May): 1203-35 .1983 "Restricted Access in Networks and Models of Power." American Journal of Sociology 88 (January): 686-17 Merton, Robert 1947 "Manifest and Latent Functions." Pp 19-84 in Social Theory and Social Structure New York: Free Press Mintz, Beth, and Michael Schwartz 1985 The Power Structure of American Business Chicago: University of Chicago Press North, D., and R Thomas 1973 The Rise of the Western World Cambridge: Cambridge University Press Okun, Arthur 1981 Prices and Quantities Washington, D.C.: Brookings Pakes, Ariel, and S Nitzan 1982 "Optimum Contracts for Research Personnel, Research Employment and the Establishment of 'Rival' Enterprises." NBER Working Paper no 871 Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research Parsons, Talcott 1937 The Structure of Social Action New York: Macmillan Pfeffer, Jeffrey 1983 "Organizational Demography." In Research in Organizational Behavior, vol Edited by L L Cummings and B Staw Greenwich, Conn.: JAI Phelps Brown, Ernest Henry 1977 The Inequality of Pay Berkeley: University of California Press Piore, Michael 1975 "Notes for a Theory of Labor Market Stratification." Pp 125-50 in Labor Market Segmentation, edited by R Edwards, M Reich, and D Gordon Lexington, Mass.: Heath , ed 1979 Unemployment and Inflation White Plains, N.Y.: Sharpe Polanyi, Karl 1944 The Great Transformation New York: Holt, Rinehart Polanyi, Karl, C Arensberg, and H Pearson 1957 Trade and Market in the Early Empires New York: Free Press Popkin, Samuel 1979 The Rational Peasant Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press Rosen, Sherwin 1982 "Authority, Control and the Distribution of Earnings." Bell Journal of Economics 13 (2): 311-23 Samuelson, Paul 1947 Foundations of Economic Analysis Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press 509 This content downloaded from 121.33.190.134 on Wed, 22 Oct 2014 05:15:45 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions American Journal of Sociology Schneider, Harold 1974 Economic Man: The Anthropology of Economics New York: Free Press Schotter, Andrew 1981 The Economic Theory of Social Institutions New York: Cambridge University Press Scott, James 1976 The Moral Economy of the Peasant New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press Shenon, Philip 1984 "Margolies Is Found Guilty of Murdering Two Women." New York Times (June 1) Simon, Herbert 1957 Administrative Behavior Glencoe, Ill.: Free Press Smith, Adam (1776) 1979 The Wealth of Nations Edited by Andrew Skinner Baltimore: Penguin Stearns, Linda 1982 "Corporate Dependency and the Structure of the Capital Market: 1880-1980." Ph.D dissertation, State University of New York at Stony Brook Thompson, E P 1971 "The Moral Economy of the English Crowd in the Eighteenth Century." Past and Present 50 (February): 76-136 Useem, Michael 1979 "The Social Organization of the American Business Elite and Participation of Corporation Directors in the Governance of American Institutions." American Sociological Review 44:553-72 Webster, Frederick, and Yoram Wind 1972 Organizational Buying Behavior Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall White, Harrison C 1981 "Where Do Markets Come From?" American Journal of Sociology 87 (November): 517-47 Williamson, Oliver 1975 Markets and Hierarchies New York: Free Press 1979 "Transaction-Cost Economics: The Governance of Contractual Relations." Journal of Law and Economics 22 (2): 233-61 1981 "The Economics of Organization: The Transaction Cost Approach." American Journal of Sociology 87 (November): 548-77 Williamson, Oliver, and William Ouchi 1981 "The Markets and Hierarchies and Visible Hand Perspectives." Pp 347-70 in Perspectives on Organizational Design and Behavior, edited by Andrew Van de Ven and William Joyce New York: Wiley Wrong, Dennis 1961 "The Oversocialized Conception of Man in Modern Sociology." American Sociological Review 26 (2): 183-93 510 This content downloaded from 121.33.190.134 on Wed, 22 Oct 2014 05:15:45 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions [...]... scale The Hobbesian problem is truly a problem, but in transcending it by the smoothing effect of social structure, we also introduce the possibility of disruptions on a larger scale than those available in the "state of nature." The embeddedness approach to the problem of trust and order in economic life, then, threads its way between the oversocialized approach of generalized morality and the undersocialized... only that there is a place for sociologists in the study of economic life but that their perspective is urgently required there In avoiding the analysis of phenomena at the center of standard economic theory, sociologists have unnecessarily cut themselves off from a large and important aspect of social life and from the European tradition-stemming especially from Max Weber-in which economic action is... any dispute if you keep the lawyers and accountants out of it They just do not understand the give -and- take needed in business.' Law suits for breach of contract appear to be rare" (1963, p 61) He goes on to explain that the top executivesof the two firmsmayknoweachother.Theymaysit together on governmentor trade committees.They may know each other socially and even belongto the samecountryclub Even... by the markets and hierarchies question The extent of vertical integration and the reasons for the persistence of small firms operating through the market are not only narrow concerns of industrial organization; they are of interest to all students of the institutions of advanced capitalism Similar issues arise in the analysis of "dual economy," dependent development, and the nature of modern corporate... one of impersonal, institutional arrangements by following and analyzing concrete patterns of social relations Unlike either alternative, or the Hobbesian position, it makes no sweeping (and thus unlikely) predictions of universal order or disorder but rather assumes that the details of social structure will determine which is found THE PROBLEMOF MARKETSAND HIERARCHIES As a concrete application of the. .. 1979 "Transaction-Cost Economics: The Governance of Contractual Relations." Journal of Law and Economics 22 (2): 233-61 1981 "The Economics of Organization: The Transaction Cost Approach." American Journal of Sociology 87 (November): 548-77 Williamson, Oliver, and William Ouchi 1981 "The Markets and Hierarchies and Visible Hand Perspectives." Pp 347-70 in Perspectives on Organizational Design and Behavior,... in explanation and prediction between Williamson's markets and hierarchies approach and the embeddedness view offered here Williamson explains the inhibition of "'opportunism"or malfeasance in economic life and the general existence of cooperation and order by the subsumption of complex economic activity in hierarchically integrated firms The empirical evidence that I cite shows, rather, that even... to deflect the analysis of institutions from sociological, historical, and legal argumentation and show instead that they arise as the efficient solution to economic problems This mission and the pervasive functionalism it implies discourage the detailed analysis of social structure that I argue here is the key to understanding how existing institutions arrived at their present state Insofar as rational... Terms and Conditions Embeddedness nisms is the impact of such change on the social relations in which economic life is embedded If this is so, no adequate link between macro- and micro-level theories can be established without a much fuller understanding of these relations The use of embeddedness analysis in explicating proximate causes of patterns of macro-level interest is well illustrated by the markets... actors, they generate clearly defined standards of behavior easily policed by the quick spread of information about instances of malfeasance But the temptations posed by this level of trust are considerable, and the diamond trade has also been the scene of numerous wellpublicized "insider job" thefts and of the notorious "CBS murders" of April 1982 In this case, the owner of a diamond company was defrauding ... view of embeddedness alters our theoretical and empirical approach to the study of economic behavior I first narrow the focus to the question of trust and malfeasance in economic life and then... disorder but rather assumes that the details of social structure will determine which is found THE PROBLEMOF MARKETSAND HIERARCHIES As a concrete application of the embeddedness approach to economic. .. atomized, undersocialized conception of human action, continuing in the utilitarian tradition The theoretical arguments disallow by hypothesis any impact of social structure and social relations

Ngày đăng: 16/02/2016, 10:50

Từ khóa liên quan

Mục lục

  • Article Contents

    • p. 481

    • p. 482

    • p. 483

    • p. 484

    • p. 485

    • p. 486

    • p. 487

    • p. 488

    • p. 489

    • p. 490

    • p. 491

    • p. 492

    • p. 493

    • p. 494

    • p. 495

    • p. 496

    • p. 497

    • p. 498

    • p. 499

    • p. 500

Tài liệu cùng người dùng

Tài liệu liên quan