Fundamentals of Corporate Finance Phần 10 potx

57 575 0
Fundamentals of Corporate Finance Phần 10 potx

Đang tải... (xem toàn văn)

Tài liệu hạn chế xem trước, để xem đầy đủ mời bạn chọn Tải xuống

Thông tin tài liệu

584 SECTION SIX federal court. Then the Hixon family, descendants of AMP’s co-founder, made public a letter to AMP’s management expressing “dismay” and asking, “Who do management and the board work for? The central issue is that AMP’s management will not permit shareholders to voice their will.” 7 As the weeks passed, AMP’s defenses, while still intact, did not look quite so strong. By mid-October, it became clear that AMP would not receive timely help from the Pennsylvania legislature. In November, the federal court gave AlliedSignal the go-ahead to ask shareholders to vote to remove the poison pill. Remember, 72 percent of its stock- holders had already accepted AlliedSignal’s tender offer. Then, suddenly, AMP gave up: management had found a white knight when Tyco International came to its rescue. Tyco was prepared to offer stock worth $55 for each AMP share. AlliedSignal dropped out of the bidding; it didn’t think AMP was worth that much. What are the lessons? First, the example illustrates some of the stratagems of merger warfare. Firms like AMP that are worried about being taken over usually prepare their defenses in advance. Often they will persuade shareholders to agree to shark-repellent changes to the corporate charter. For example, the charter may be amended to require that any merger must be approved by a supermajority of 80 percent of the shares rather than the normal 50 percent. Firms frequently deter potential bidders by devising poison pills, which make the company unappetizing. For example, the poison pill may give existing shareholders the right to buy the company’s shares at half price as soon as a bidder acquires more than 15 percent of the shares. The bidder is not entitled to the discount. Thus the bidder re- sembles Tantalus—as soon as it has acquired 15 percent of the shares, control is lifted away from its reach. The battle for AMP demonstrates the strength of poison pills and other takeover de- fenses. AlliedSignal’s offensive still gained ground, but with great expense and effort and at a very slow pace. The second lesson of the AMP story is the potential power of institutional investors. The main reason that AMP caved in was not failure of its legal defenses but economic pressure from its major shareholders. Did AMP’s management and board act in the shareholders’ interests? In the end, yes. They said that AMP was worth more than AlliedSignal’s offer, and they found another buyer to prove them right. However, they would not have searched for a white knight absent AlliedSignal’s bid. WHO GETS THE GAINS? Is it better to own shares in the acquiring firm or the target? In general, shareholders of the target firm do best. Franks, Harris, and Titman studied 399 acquisitions by large U.S. firms between 1975 and 1984. They found that shareholders who sold following the announcement of the bid received a healthy gain averaging 28 percent. 8 On the other hand, it appears that investors expected acquiring companies to just about break even. WHITE KNIGHT Friendly potential acquirer sought by a target company threatened by an unwelcome suitor. SHARK REPELLENT Amendments to a company charter made to forestall takeover attempts. 7 S. Lipin and G. Fairclothy, “AMP’s Antitakeover Tactics Rile Holder,” The Wall Street Journal, October 5, 1998, p. A18. 8 J. R. Franks, R. S. Harris, and S. Titman, “The Postmerger Share-Price Performance of Acquiring Firms,” Journal of Financial Economics 29 (March 1991), pp. 81–96. Mergers, Acquisitions, and Corporate Control 585 The prices of their shares fell by 1 percent. 9 The value of the total package—buyer plus seller—increased by 4 percent. Of course, these are averages; selling shareholders sometimes obtain much higher returns. When IBM took over Lotus, it paid a premium of 100 percent, or about $1.7 billion, for Lotus stock. Why do sellers earn higher returns? The most important reason is the competition among potential bidders. Once the first bidder puts the target company “in play,” one or more additional suitors often jump in, sometimes as white knights at the invitation of the target firm’s management. Every time one suitor tops another’s bid, more of the merger gain slides toward the target. At the same time the target firm’s management may mount various legal and financial counterattacks, ensuring that capitulation, if and when it comes, is at the highest attainable price. Of course, bidders and targets are not the only possible winners. Unsuccessful bid- ders often win, too, by selling off their holdings in target companies at substantial prof- its. Such shares may be sold on the open market or sold back to the target company. 10 Sometimes they are sold to the successful suitor. Other winners include investment bankers, lawyers, accountants, and in some cases arbitrageurs, or “arbs,” who speculate on the likely success of takeover bids. “Speculate” has a negative ring, but it can be a useful social service. A tender offer may present shareholders with a difficult decision. Should they accept, should they wait to see if someone else produces a better offer, or should they sell their stock in the market? This quandary presents an opportunity for the arbitrageurs. In other words, they buy from the target’s shareholders and take on the risk that the deal will not go through. 11 Leveraged Buyouts Leveraged buyouts, or LBOs, differ from ordinary acquisitions in two ways. First, a large fraction of the purchase price is debt-financed. Some, perhaps all, of this debt is junk, that is, below investment grade. Second, the shares of the LBO no longer trade on the open market. The remaining equity in the LBO is privately held by a small group of (usually institutional) investors. When this group is led by the company’s management, the acquisition is called a management buyout (MBO). Many LBOs are in fact MBOs. In the 1970s and 1980s many management buyouts were arranged for unwanted di- visions of large, diversified companies. Smaller divisions outside the companies’ main lines of business often lacked top management’s interest and commitment, and divi- sional management chafed under corporate bureaucracy. Many such divisions flowered when spun off as MBOs. Their managers, pushed by the need to generate cash for debt service and encouraged by a substantial personal stake in the business, found ways to cut costs and compete more effectively. During the 1980s MBO/LBO activity shifted to buyouts of entire businesses, including large, mature public corporations. The largest, most dramatic, and best- 9 The small loss to the shareholders of acquiring firms is not statistically significant. Other studies using dif- ferent samples have observed a small positive return. 10 When a potential acquirer sells the shares back to the target, the transaction is known as greenmail. 11 Strictly speaking, an arbitrageur is an investor who makes a riskless profit. Arbitrageurs in merger battles often take very large risks indeed. Their activities are sometimes known as “risk arbitrage.” 586 SECTION SIX documented LBO of them all was the $25 billion takeover of RJR Nabisco in 1988 by Kohlberg Kravis Roberts (KKR). The players, tactics, and controversies of LBOs are writ large in this case. ᭤ EXAMPLE 4 RJR Nabisco 12 On October 28, 1988, the board of directors of RJR Nabisco revealed that Ross John- son, the company’s chief executive officer, had formed a group of investors prepared to buy all the firm’s stock for $75 per share in cash and take the company private. John- son’s group was backed up and advised by Shearson Lehman Hutton, the investment bank subsidiary of American Express. RJR’s share price immediately moved to about $75, handing shareholders a 36 per- cent gain over the previous day’s price of $56. At the same time RJR’s bonds fell, since it was clear that existing bondholders would soon have a lot more company. Johnson’s offer lifted RJR onto the auction block. Once the company was in play, its board of directors was obliged to consider other offers, which were not long coming. Four days later, a group of investors led by LBO specialists Kohlberg Kravis Roberts bid $90 per share, $79 in cash plus preferred stock valued at $11. The bidding finally closed on November 30, some 32 days after the initial offer was revealed. In the end it was Johnson’s group against KKR. KKR offered $109 per share, after adding $1 per share (roughly $230 million) at the last hour. The KKR bid was $81 in cash, convertible subordinated debentures valued at about $10, and preferred shares valued at about $18. Johnson’s group bid $112 in cash and securities. But the RJR board chose KKR. True, Johnson’s group had offered $3 per share more, but its security valuations were viewed as “softer” and perhaps overstated. Also, KKR’s planned asset sales were less drastic; perhaps their plans for managing the business in- spired more confidence. Finally, the Johnson group’s proposal contained a management compensation package that seemed extremely generous and had generated an avalanche of bad press. But where did the merger benefits come from? What could justify offering $109 per share, about $25 billion in all, for a company that only 33 days previously had been sell- ing for $56 per share? KKR and other bidders were betting on two things. First, they expected to generate billions of additional dollars from interest tax shields, reduced capital expenditures, and sales of assets not strictly necessary to RJR’s core businesses. Asset sales alone were projected to generate $5 billion. Second, they expected to make those core businesses significantly more profitable, mainly by cutting back on expenses and bureaucracy. Ap- parently there was plenty to cut, including the RJR “Air Force,” which at one point op- erated 10 corporate jets. In the year after KKR took over, new management was installed. This group sold as- sets and cut back operating expenses and capital spending. There were also layoffs. As expected, high interest charges meant a net loss of $976 million for 1989, but pretax op- erating income actually increased, despite extensive asset sales, including the sale of RJR’s European food operations. While management was cutting costs and selling assets, prices in the junk bond mar- 12 The story of the RJR Nabisco buyout is reconstructed by B. Burrough and J. Helyar in Barbarians at the Gate: The Fall of RJR Nabisco (New York: Harper & Row, 1990) and is the subject of a movie with the same title. Mergers, Acquisitions, and Corporate Control 587 ket were rapidly declining, implying much higher future interest charges for RJR and stricter terms on any refinancing. In mid-1990 KKR made an additional equity invest- ment, and later that year the company announced an offer of cash and new shares in ex- change for $753 million of junk bonds. By 1993 the burden of debt had been reduced from $26 billion to $14 billion. For RJR, the world’s largest LBO, it seemed that high debt was a temporary, not permanent, virtue. BARBARIANS AT THE GATE? The buyout of RJR crystallized views on LBOs, the junk bond market, and the takeover business. For many it exemplified all that was wrong with finance in the 1980s, espe- cially the willingness of “raiders” to carve up established companies, leaving them with enormous debt burdens, basically in order to get rich quick. There was plenty of confusion, stupidity, and greed in the LBO business. Not all the people involved were nice. On the other hand, LBOs generated enormous increases in market value, and most of the gains went to selling stockholders, not raiders. For ex- ample, the biggest winners in the RJR Nabisco LBO were the company’s stockholders. We should therefore consider briefly where these gains may have come from before we try to pass judgment on LBOs. There are several possibilities. The Junk Bond Markets. LBOs and debt-financed takeovers may have been driven by artificially cheap funding from the junk bond markets. With hindsight it seems that investors in junk bonds underestimated the risks of default. Default rates climbed painfully between 1989 and 1991. At the same time the junk bond market became much less liquid after the demise of Drexel Burnham Lambert, the chief market maker. Yields rose dramatically, and new issues dried up. Suddenly junk-financed LBOs seemed to disappear from the scene. 13 Leverage and Taxes. As we explained earlier, borrowing money saves taxes. But taxes were not the main driving force behind LBOs. The value of interest tax shields was just not big enough to explain the observed gains in market value. Of course, if interest tax shields were the main motive for LBOs’ high debt, then LBO managers would not be so concerned to pay off debt. We saw that this was one of the first tasks facing RJR Nabisco’s new management. Other Stakeholders. It is possible that the gain to the selling stockholders is just someone else’s loss and that no value is generated overall. Therefore, we should look at the total gain to all investors in an LBO, not just the selling stockholders. Bondholders are the obvious losers. The debt they thought was well-secured may turn into junk when the borrower goes through an LBO. We noted how market prices of RJR Nabisco debt fell sharply when Ross Johnson’s first LBO offer was announced. But again, the value losses suffered by bondholders in LBOs are not nearly large enough to explain stockholder gains. Leverage and Incentives. Managers and employees of LBOs work harder and often smarter. They have to generate cash to service the extra debt. Moreover, managers’ 13 There was a sharp revival of junk bond sales in 1992 and 1993 and 1996 was a banner year. But many of these issues simply replaced existing bonds. It remains to be seen whether junk bonds will make a lasting re- covery. 588 SECTION SIX personal fortunes are riding on the LBO’s success. They become owners rather than or- ganization men or women. It is hard to measure the payoff from better incentives, but there is some evidence of improved operating efficiency in LBOs. Kaplan, who studied 48 management buyouts between 1980 and 1986, found average increases in operating income of 24 percent over the following 3 years. Ratios of operating income and net cash flow to assets and sales increased dramatically. He observed cutbacks in capital expenditures but not in em- ployment. Kaplan suggests that these operating changes “are due to improved incen- tives rather than layoffs or managerial exploitation of shareholders through inside in- formation.” 14 Free Cash Flow. The free-cash-flow theory of takeovers is basically that mature firms with a surplus of cash will tend to waste it. This contrasts with standard finance theory, which says that firms with more cash than positive-NPV investment opportunities should give the cash back to investors through higher dividends or share repurchases. But we see firms like RJR Nabisco spending on corporate luxuries and questionable capital investments. One benefit of LBOs is to put such companies on a diet and force them to pay out cash to service debt. The free-cash-flow theory predicts that mature, “cash cow” companies will be the most likely targets of LBOs. We can find many examples that fit the theory, including RJR Nabisco. The theory says that the gains in market value generated by LBOs are just the present values of the future cash flows that would otherwise have been frittered away. 15 We do not endorse the free-cash-flow theory as the sole explanation for LBOs. We have mentioned several other plausible rationales, and we suspect that most LBOs are driven by a mixture of motives. Nor do we say that all LBOs are beneficial. On the con- trary, there are many mistakes and even soundly motivated LBOs can be dangerous, as the bankruptcies of Campeau, Revco, National Gypsum, and many other highly lever- aged companies prove. However, we do take issue with those who portray LBOs simply as Wall Street barbarians breaking up the traditional strengths of corporate America. In many cases LBOs have generated true gains. In the next section we sum up the long-run impact of mergers and acquisitions, in- cluding LBOs, in the United States economy. We warn you, however, that there are no neat answers. Our assessment has to be mixed and tentative. Mergers and the Economy MERGER WAVES Mergers come in waves. The first episode of intense merger activity occurred at the turn of the twentieth century and the second in the 1920s. There was a further boom from 1967 to 1969 and then again in the 1980s and 1990s. Each episode coincided with a pe- 14 S. Kaplan, “The Effects of Management Buyouts on Operating Performance and Value,” Journal of Finan- cial Economics 24 (October 1989), pp. 217–254. 15 The free-cash-flow theory’s chief proponent is Michael Jensen. See M. C. Jensen, “The Eclipse of the Pub- lic Corporation,” Harvard Business Review 67 (September–October 1989), pp. 61–74, and “The Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow, Corporate Finance and Takeovers,” American Economic Review 76 (May 1986), pp. 323–329. Mergers, Acquisitions, and Corporate Control 589 riod of buoyant stock prices, though in each case there were substantial differences in the types of companies that merged and how they went about it. We don’t really understand why merger activity is so volatile. If mergers are prompted by economic motives, at least one of these motives must be “here today, gone tomorrow,” and it must somehow be associated with high stock prices. But none of the economic motives that we review in this material has anything to do with the general level of the stock market. None of the motives burst on the scene in 1967, departed in 1970, reappeared for most of the 1980s, and reappeared again in the mid-1990s. Some mergers may result from mistakes in valuation on the part of the stock market. In other words, the buyer may believe that investors have underestimated the value of the seller or may hope that they will overestimate the value of the combined firm. Why don’t we see just as many firms hunting for bargain acquisitions when the stock market is low? It is possible that “suckers are born every minute,” but it’s difficult to believe that they can be harvested only in bull markets. During the 1980s merger boom, only the very largest companies were immune from attack from a rival management team. For example, in 1985 Pantry Pride, a small su- permarket chain recently emerged from bankruptcy, made a bid for the cosmetics com- pany Revlon. Revlon’s assets were more than five times those of Pantry Pride. What made the bid possible (and eventually successful) was the ability of Pantry Pride to fi- nance the takeover by borrowing $2.1 billion. The growth of leveraged buyouts during the 1980s depended on the development of a junk bond market that allowed bidders to place low-grade bonds rapidly and in high volume. By the end of the decade the merger environment had changed. Many of the obvious targets had disappeared, and the battle for RJR Nabisco highlighted the increasing cost of victory. Institutions were reluctant to increase their holdings of junk bonds. More- over, the market for these bonds had depended to a remarkable extent on one individ- ual, Michael Milken, of the investment bank Drexel Burnham Lambert. By the late 1980s Milken and his employer were in trouble. Milken was indicted by a grand jury on 98 counts and was subsequently sentenced to jail and ordered to pay $600 million. Drexel filed for bankruptcy, but by that time the junk bond market was moribund and the finance for highly leveraged buyouts had largely dried up. 16 Finally, in reaction to the perceived excess of the merger boom, the state legislatures and the courts began to lean against takeovers. The decline in merger activity proved temporary; by the mid-1990s stock markets and mergers were booming again. However, LBOs remained out of fashion, and rela- tively few mergers were intended simply to replace management. Instead, companies began to look once more at the possible benefits from combining two businesses. DO MERGERS GENERATE NET BENEFITS? There are undoubtedly good acquisitions and bad acquisitions, but economists find it hard to agree on whether acquisitions are beneficial on balance. We do know that merg- ers generate substantial gains to stockholders of acquired firms. Since buyers seem roughly to break even and sellers make substantial gains, it seems that there are positive gains to mergers. But not everybody is convinced. Some believe that investors analyzing mergers pay too much attention to short-term earnings gains and don’t notice that these gains are at the expense of long-term prospects. 16 For a history of the role of Milken in the development of the junk bond market, see C. Bruck, The Preda- tor’s Ball: The Junk Bond Raiders and the Man Who Staked Them (New York: Simon and Schuster, 1988). 590 SECTION SIX Since we can’t observe how companies would have fared in the absence of a merger, it is difficult to measure the effects on profitability. Studies of recent merger activity suggest that mergers do seem to improve real productivity. For example, Healy, Palepu, and Ruback examined 50 large mergers between 1979 and 1983 and found an average increase in the companies’ pretax returns of 2.4 percentage points. 17 They argue that this gain came from generating a higher level of sales from the same assets. There was no evidence that the companies were mortgaging their long-term futures by cutting back on long-term investments; expenditures on capital equipment and research and devel- opment tracked the industry average. If you are concerned with public policy toward mergers, you do not want to look only at their impact on the shareholders of the companies concerned. For instance, we have already seen that in the case of RJR Nabisco some part of the shareholders’ gain was at the expense of the bondholders and the Internal Revenue Service (through the enlarged interest tax shield). The acquirer’s shareholders may also gain at the expense of the tar- get firm’s employees, who in some cases are laid off or are forced to take pay cuts after takeovers. Many people believe that the merger wave of the 1980s led to excessive debt levels and left many companies ill-equipped to survive a recession. Also, many savings and loan companies and some large insurance firms invested heavily in junk bonds. De- faults on these bonds threatened, and in some cases extinguished, their solvency. Perhaps the most important effect of acquisition is felt by the managers of compa- nies that are not taken over. For example, one effect of LBOs was that the managers of even the largest corporations could not feel safe from challenge. Perhaps the threat of takeover spurs the whole of corporate America to try harder. Unfortunately, we don’t know whether on balance the threat of merger makes for more active days or sleepless nights. We do know that merger activity is very costly. For example, in the RJR Nabisco buyout, the total fees paid to the investment banks, lawyers, and accountants amounted to over $1 billion. Even if the gains to the community exceed these costs, one wonders whether the same benefits could not be achieved more cheaply another way. For example, are lever- aged buyouts necessary to make managers work harder? Perhaps the problem lies in the way that many corporations reward and penalize their managers. Perhaps many of the gains from takeover could be captured by linking management compensation more closely to performance. Summary In what ways do companies change the composition of their ownership or man- agement? If the board of directors fails to replace an inefficient management, there are four ways to effect a change: (1) shareholders may engage in a proxy contest to replace the board; (2) the firm may be acquired by another; (3) the firm may be purchased by a private group of investors in a leveraged buyout, or (4) it may sell off part of its operations to another Mergers, Acquisitions, and Corporate Control 591 company. There are three ways for one firm to acquire another: (1) it can merge all the assets and liabilities of the target firm into those of its own company; (2) it can buy the stock of the target; or (3) it can buy the individual assets of the target. The offer to buy the stock of the target firm is called a tender offer. The purchase of the stock or assets of another firm is called an acquisition. Why may it make sense for companies to merge? A merger may be undertaken in order to replace an inefficient management. But sometimes two business may be more valuable together than apart. Gains may stem from economies of scale, economies of vertical integration, the combination of complementary resources, or redeployment of surplus funds. We don’t know how frequently these benefits occur, but they do make economic sense. Sometimes mergers are undertaken to diversify risks or artificially increase growth of earnings per share. These motives are dubious. How should the gains and costs of mergers to the acquiring firm be measured? A merger generates an economic gain if the two firms are worth more together than apart. The gain is the difference between the value of the merged firm and the value of the two firms run independently. The cost is the premium that the buyer pays for the selling firm over its value as a separate entity. When payment is in the form of shares, the value of this payment naturally depends on what those shares are worth after the merger is complete. You should go ahead with the merger if the gain exceeds the cost. What are some takeover defenses? Mergers are often amicably negotiated between the management and directors of the two companies; but if the seller is reluctant, the would-be buyer can decide to make a tender offer for the stock. We sketched some of the offensive and defensive tactics used in takeover battles. These defenses include shark repellents (changes in the company charter meant to make a takeover more difficult to achieve), poison pills (measures that make takeover of the firm more costly), and the search for white knights (the attempt to find a friendly acquirer before the unfriendly one takes over the firm). Do mergers increase efficiency and how are the gains from mergers distributed be- tween shareholders of the acquired and acquiring firms? We observed that when the target firm is acquired, its shareholders typically win: target firms’ shareholders earn abnormally large returns. The bidding firm’s shareholders roughly break even. This suggests that the typical merger appears to generate positive net benefits, but competition among bidders and active defense by management of the target firm pushes most of the gains toward selling shareholders. Mergers seem to generate economic gains, but they are also costly. Investment bankers, lawyers, and arbitrageurs thrived during the 1980s merger and LBO boom. Many companies were left with heavy debt burdens and had to sell assets or improve performance to stay solvent. By the end of 1990, the new-issue junk bond market had dried up, and the corporate jousting field was strangely quiet. But not for long. As we write this material early in 2000, stock markets and mergers are again booming. What are some of the motivations for leveraged and management buyouts of the firm? In a leveraged buyout (LBO) or management buyout (MBO), all public shares are repurchased and the company “goes private.” LBOs tend to involve mature businesses with ample cash flow and modest growth opportunities. LBOs and other debt-financed takeovers 592 SECTION SIX are driven by a mixture of motives, including (1) the value of interest tax shields; (2) transfers of value from bondholders, who may see the value of their bonds fall as the firm piles up more debt; and (3) the opportunity to create better incentives for managers and employees, who have a personal stake in the company. In addition, many LBOs have been designed to force firms with surplus cash to distribute it to shareholders rather than plowing it back. Investors feared such companies would otherwise channel free cash flow into negative-NPV investments. www.secdata.com/ Good source of merger data www.mergernetwork.com/ Information about mergers and acquisitions http://viking.som.yale.edu/will/finman540/acquira3.htm A sample case looking at an acquisi- tion www.lens-inc.com/ Active corporate governance strategies www.corpgov.net/ The Corporate Governance Network proxy contest acquisition poison pill merger leveraged buyout (LBO) white knight tender offer management buyout (MBO) shark repellent 1. Merger Motives. Which of the following motives for mergers make economic sense? a. Merging to achieve economies of scale. b. Merging to reduce risk by diversification. c. Merging to redeploy cash generated by a firm with ample profits but limited growth op- portunities. d. Merging to increase earnings per share. 2. Merger Motives. Explain why it might make good sense for Northeast Heating and North- east Air Conditioning to merge into one company. 3. Empirical Facts. True or false? a. Sellers almost always gain in mergers. b. Buyers almost always gain in mergers. c. Firms that do unusually well tend to be acquisition targets. d. Merger activity in the United States varies dramatically from year to year. e. On the average, mergers produce substantial economic gains. f. Tender offers require the approval of the selling firm’s management. g. The cost of a merger is always independent of the economic gain produced by the merger. 4. Merger Tactics. Connect each term to its correct definition or description: A. LBO 1. Attempt to gain control of a firm by winning the votes of its B. Poison pill stockholders. C. Tender offer 2. Changes in corporate charter designed to deter unwelcome D. Shark repellent takeover. E. Proxy contest 3. Friendly potential acquirer sought by a threatened target firm. Related Web Links Key Terms Quiz Mergers, Acquisitions, and Corporate Control 593 F. White knight 4. Shareholders are issued rights to buy shares if bidder acquires large stake in the firm. 5. Offer to buy shares directly from stockholders. 6. Company or business bought out by private investors, largely debt-financed. 5. Empirical Facts. True or false? a. One of the first tasks of an LBO’s financial manager is to pay down debt. b. Shareholders of bidding companies earn higher abnormal returns when the merger is fi- nanced with stock than in cash-financed deals. c. Targets for LBOs in the 1980s tended to be profitable companies in mature industries with limited investment opportunities. 6. Merger Gains. Acquiring Corp. is considering a takeover of Takeover Target Inc. Acquiring has 10 million shares outstanding, which sell for $40 each. Takeover Target has 5 million shares outstanding, which sell for $20 each. If the merger gains are estimated at $20 million, what is the highest price per share that Acquiring should be willing to pay to Takeover Tar- get shareholders? 7. Mergers and P/E Ratios. If Acquiring Corp. from problem 6 has a price-earnings ratio of 12, and Takeover Target has a P/E ratio of 8, what should be the P/E ratio of the merged firm? Assume in this case that the merger is financed by an issue of new Acquiring Corp. shares. Takeover Target will get one Acquiring share for every two Takeover Target shares held. 8. Merger Gains and Costs. Velcro Saddles is contemplating the acquisition of Pogo Ski Sticks, Inc. The values of the two companies as separate entities are $20 million and $10 mil- lion, respectively. Velcro Saddles estimates that by combining the two companies, it will re- duce marketing and administrative costs by $500,000 per year in perpetuity. Velcro Saddles is willing to pay $14 million cash for Pogo. The opportunity cost of capital is 10 percent. a. What is the gain from merger? b. What is the cost of the cash offer? c. What is the NPV of the acquisition under the cash offer? 9. Stock versus Cash Offers. Suppose that instead of making a cash offer as in problem 8, Vel- cro Saddles considers offering Pogo shareholders a 50 percent holding in Velcro Saddles. a. What is the value of the stock in the merged company held by the original Pogo share- holders? b. What is the cost of the stock alternative? c. What is its NPV under the stock offer? 10. Merger Gains. Immense Appetite, Inc., believes that it can acquire Sleepy Industries and improve efficiency to the extent that the market value of Sleepy will increase by $5 million. Sleepy currently sells for $20 a share, and there are 1 million shares outstanding. a. Sleepy’s management is willing to accept a cash offer of $25 a share. Can the merger be accomplished on a friendly basis? b. What will happen if Sleepy’s management holds out for an offer of $28 a share? 11. Mergers and P/E Ratios. Castles in the Sand currently sells at a price-earnings multiple of 10. The firm has 2 million shares outstanding, and sells at a price per share of $40. Firm Practice Problems [...]... for the risk of the project, so the opportunity cost of capital for the project is 5 + 10 = 15 percent Notice that KW’s opportunity cost of capital is stated in terms of the return on a dollar-denominated investment, but the cash flows are given in leos A project that offers a 15 percent expected return in leos could fall far short of offering the required return in dollars if the value of the leo is... example, suppose you have agreed to buy a shipment of Japanese VCRs for 100 million and to make the payment when you take delivery of the VCRs at the end of 12 months You could wait until the 12 months have passed and then buy 100 million yen at the spot exchange rate If the spot rate is unchanged at 107 .52/$, then the VCRs will cost you 100 million /107 .52 = $930,060 But you are taking a risk by waiting,... United States: peso price of goods in Mexico number of pesos per dollar peso price of gold in Mexico $300 = 9.438 Price of gold in Mexico = 300 × 9.438 = 2,831 pesos Dollar price of goods in USA = No one who has compared prices in foreign stores with prices at home really believes that the law of one price holds exactly Look at the first column of Table 6.6, which Activity of this kind is known as arbitrage... can fix in advance the number of dollars that you will need to lay out With a forward rate of peso12.00/$, you need to set aside 1,252,500/12.00 = $104 ,375 Thus, after paying off your peso loan, you walk away with a risk-free profit of $112,312 – $104 ,375 = $7,937 It is a pity that in practice interest rate parity almost always holds and the opportunities for such easy profits are rare ᭤ Self-Test 6... (dollar) 1.5148 7.7681 7800.00 107 .520 1.6790 1.5139 7.7687 7952.5 105 .865 1.665 1.5133 7.896 8487.5 101 .3 1.6358 Note: Rates show the number of units of foreign currency per dollar (indirect quotes), except for the euro and the U.K pound, which show the number of dollars per unit of foreign currency (direct quotes) Source: From Financial Times, October 7, 1999 Used by permission of Financial Times 600 SECTION... $1,000 worth of oranges from a California farmer? How many dollars will it take for that farmer to buy a Japanese VCR priced in Japan at 30,000 yen (¥)? The exchange rate is 107 .52 per dollar The $1,000 of oranges will require the Japanese importer to come up with 1,000 × 107 .52 = 107 ,520 The VCR will require the American importer to come up with 30,000 /107 .52 = $279 ᭤ Self-Test 1 SPOT RATE OF EXCHANGE... Leisure Products pays $25 in cash for each share of Plastitoys? c What is the cost of the acquisition if Leisure Products offers one share of Leisure Products for every three shares of Plastitoys? d How would the cost of the cash offer and the share offer alter if the expected growth rate of Plastitoys were not increased by the merger? Solutions to Self-Test Questions 1 a Horizontal merger IBM is in the... the end of the year you receive your 100 million yen and hand over 100 million /101 .3 = $987,167 in payment Notice that if you buy Japanese yen forward, you get fewer yen for your dollar than if you buy spot In this case, the yen is said to trade at a forward premium relative to the dollar Expressed as a percentage, the 1-year forward premium is 107 .52 – 101 .3 101 .3 × 100 = 6.14% You could also say that... pesos for 4,000/9.438 = $424 You have made a gross profit of $124 an ounce Of course, you have to pay transportation and insurance costs out of this, but there should still be something left over for you You returned from your trip with a sure-fire profit But sure-fire profits don’t exist— not for long As others notice the disparity between the price of gold in Mexico and the FIGURE 6.1 Some simple theories... and that will force down the price of the domestic product Similarly, those goods that can be bought more cheaply in the United States will be exported, and that will force down the price of the foreign product This conclusion is often called the law of one price Just as the price of goods in Safeway must be roughly the same as the price of goods in A&P, so the price of goods in Mexico when converted . opportunity cost of capital is 10 percent. a. What is the gain from merger? b. What is the cost of the cash offer? c. What is the NPV of the acquisition under the cash offer? 9. Stock versus Cash Offers liabilities of the target firm into those of its own company; (2) it can buy the stock of the target; or (3) it can buy the individual assets of the target. The offer to buy the stock of the target. price of the foreign product. This conclusion is often called the law of one price. Just as the price of goods in Safeway must be roughly the same as the price of goods in A&P, so the price of

Ngày đăng: 05/08/2014, 13:20

Từ khóa liên quan

Tài liệu cùng người dùng

  • Đang cập nhật ...

Tài liệu liên quan