Recursive macroeconomic theory, Thomas Sargent 2nd Ed - Chapter 10 pps

11 305 0
Recursive macroeconomic theory, Thomas Sargent 2nd Ed - Chapter 10 pps

Đang tải... (xem toàn văn)

Tài liệu hạn chế xem trước, để xem đầy đủ mời bạn chọn Tải xuống

Thông tin tài liệu

Chapter 10 Ricardian Equivalence 10.1 Borrowing limits and Ricardian equivalence This chapter studies whether the timing of taxes matters Under some assumptions it does, and under others it does not The Ricardian doctrine describes assumptions under which the timing of lump taxes does not matter In this chapter, we will study how the timing of taxes interacts with restrictions on the ability of households to borrow We study the issue in two equivalent settings: (1) an infinite horizon economy with an infinitely lived representative agent; and (2) an infinite horizon economy with a sequence of one-period-lived agents, each of whom cares about its immediate descendant We assume that the interest rate is exogenously given For example, the economy might be a small open economy that faces a given interest rate determined in the international capital market Chapter 13 will describe a general equilibrium analysis of the Ricardian doctrine where the interest rate is determined within the model The key findings of the chapter are that in the infinite horizon model, Ricardian equivalence holds under what we earlier called the natural borrowing limit, but not under more stringent ones The natural borrowing limit is the one that lets households borrow up to the capitalized value of their endowment sequences These results have counterparts in the overlapping generations model, since that model is equivalent to an infinite horizon model with a noborrowing constraint In the overlapping generations model, the no-borrowing constraint translates into a requirement that bequests be nonnegative Thus, in the overlapping generations model, the domain of the Ricardian proposition is restricted, at least relative to the infinite horizon model under the natural borrowing limit – 306 – Infinitely lived–agent economy 307 10.2 Infinitely lived–agent economy An economy consists of N identical households each of whom orders a stream of consumption of a single good with preferences ∞ β t u(ct ), (10.2.1) t=0 where β ∈ (0, 1) and u(·) is a strictly increasing, strictly concave, twicedifferentiable one-period utility function We impose the Inada condition lim u (c) = +∞ c↓0 This condition is important because we will be stressing the feature that c ≥ There is no uncertainty The household can invest in a single risk-free asset bearing a fixed gross one-period rate of return R > The asset is either a risk-free loan to foreigners or to the government At time t, the household faces the budget constraint ct + R−1 bt+1 ≤ yt + bt , (10.2.2) where b0 is given Throughout this chapter, we assume that Rβ = Here ∞ {yt }∞ is a given nonstochastic nonnegative endowment sequence and t=0 β t yt t=0 < ∞ We shall investigate two alternative restrictions on asset holdings {bt }∞ t=0 One is that bt ≥ for all t ≥ This restriction states that the household can lend but not borrow The alternative restriction permits the household to borrow, but only an amount that it is feasible to repay To discover this amount, set ct = for all t in formula (10.2.2 ) and solve forward for bt to get ∞ ˜t = − b R−j yt+j , (10.2.3) j=0 where we have ruled out Ponzi schemes by imposing the transversality condition lim R−T bt+T = T →∞ (10.2.4) Following Aiyagari (1994), we call ˜t the natural debt limit Even with ct = , b the consumer cannot repay more than ˜t Thus, our alternative restriction on b assets is b (10.2.5) bt ≥ ˜t , 308 Ricardian Equivalence which is evidently weaker than bt ≥ 10.2.1 Solution to consumption/savings decision Consider the household’s problem of choosing {ct , bt+1 }∞ to maximize ext=0 pression (10.2.1 ) subject to (10.2.2 ) and bt+1 ≥ for all t The first-order conditions for this problem are u (ct ) ≥ βRu (ct+1 ), ∀t ≥ 0; (10.2.6a) and u (ct ) > βRu (ct+1 ) implies bt+1 = (10.2.6b) Because βR = , these conditions and the constraint (10.2.2 ) imply that ct+1 = ct when bt+1 > ; but when the consumer is borrowing constrained, bt+1 = and yt + bt = ct < ct+1 The solution evidently depends on the {yt } path, as the following examples illustrate Example Assume b0 = and the endowment path {yt }∞ = {yh , yl , yh , yl , } , t=0 where yh > yl > The present value of the household’s endowment is ∞ ∞ β t yt = t=0 β 2t (yh + βyl ) = t=0 yh + βyl − β2 The annuity value c that has the same present value as the endowment stream ¯ is given by yh + βyl c ¯ yh + βyl = , or c = ¯ 1−β − β2 1+β The solution to the household’s optimization problem is the constant consumption stream ct = c for all t ≥ , and using the budget constraint (10.2.2 ), we ¯ can back out the associated savings scheme; bt+1 = (yh − yl )/(1 + β) for even t, and bt+1 = for odd t The consumer is never borrowing constrained We encountered a more general version of equation (10.2.5 ) in chapter when we discussed Arrow securities Note b = does not imply that the consumer is borrowing constrained t He is borrowing constrained if the Lagrange multiplier on the constraint bt ≥ is not zero Government 309 Example Assume b0 = and the endowment path {yt }∞ = {yl , yh , yl , yh , } , t=0 where yh > yl > The solution is c0 = yl and b1 = , and from period onward, the solution is the same as in example Hence, the consumer is borrowing constrained the first period Example Assume b0 = and yt = λt where < λ < R Notice that λβ < The solution with the borrowing constraint bt ≥ is ct = λt , bt = for all t ≥ The consumer is always borrowing constrained Example Assume the same b0 and endowment sequence as in example 3, but now impose only the natural borrowing constraint (10.2.5 ) The present value of the household’s endowment is ∞ β t λt = t=0 − λβ The household’s budget constraint for each t is satisfied at a constant consumption level c satisfying ˆ c ˆ = , 1−β − λβ or c = ˆ 1−β − λβ Substituting this consumption rate into formula (10.2.2 ) and solving forward gives − λt (10.2.7) bt = − βλ The consumer issues more and more debt as time passes, and uses his rising endowment to service it The consumer’s debt always satisfies the natural debt limit at t, namely, ˜t = −λt /(1 − βλ) b Example Take the specification of example 4, but now impose λ < Note that the solution (10.2.7 ) implies bt ≥ , so that the constant consumption ˆ path ct = c in example is now the solution even if the borrowing constraint bt ≥ is imposed Examples and illustrate a general result in chapter 16 Given a borrowing constraint and a non-stochastic endowment stream, the impact of the borrowing constraint will not vanish until the household reaches the period with the highest annuity value of the remainder of the endowment stream 310 Ricardian Equivalence 10.3 Government Add a government to the model The government purchases a stream {gt }∞ t=0 per household and imposes a stream of lump-sum taxes {τt }∞ on the houset=0 hold, subject to the sequence of budget constraints Bt + gt = τt + R−1 Bt+1 , (10.3.1) where Bt is one-period debt due at t, denominated in the time t consumption good, that the government owes the households or foreign investors Notice that we allow the government to borrow, even though in one of the preceding specifications, we did not permit the household to borrow (If Bt < , the government lends to households or foreign investors.) Solving the government’s budget constraint forward gives the intertemporal constraint ∞ R−j (τt+j − gt+j ) Bt = (10.3.2) j=0 for t ≥ , where we have ruled out Ponzi schemes by imposing the transversality condition lim R−T Bt+T = T →∞ 10.3.1 Effect on household We must now deduct τt from the household’s endowment in (10.2.2 ), ct + R−1 bt+1 ≤ yt − τt + bt (10.3.3) Solving this tax-adjusted budget constraint forward and invoking transversality condition (10.2.4 ) yield ∞ bt = R−j (ct+j + τt+j − yt+j ) (10.3.4) j=0 The natural debt limit is obtained by setting ct = for all t in (10.3.4 ), ∞ ˜t ≥ b j=0 R−j (τt+j − yt+j ) (10.3.5) Government 311 Notice how taxes affect ˜t [compare equations (10.2.3 ) and (10.3.5 )] b We use the following definition: Definition: Given initial conditions (b0 , B0 ), an equilibrium is a household plan {ct , bt+1 }∞ and a government policy {gt , τt , Bt+1 }∞ such that (a) the t=0 t=0 government plan satisfies the government budget constraint (10.3.1 ), and (b) given {τt }∞ , the household’s plan is optimal t=0 We can now state a Ricardian proposition under the natural debt limit Proposition 1: Suppose that the natural debt limit prevails Given initial c b g ¯ ¯ conditions (b0 , B0 ), let {¯t , ¯t+1 }∞ and {¯t , τt , Bt+1 }∞ be an equilibrium t=0 t=0 Consider any other tax policy {ˆt }∞ satisfying τ t=0 ∞ −t ∞ R τt = ˆ t=0 R−t τt ¯ (10.3.6) t=0 Then {¯t , ˆt+1 }∞ and {¯t , τt , Bt+1 }∞ is also an equilibrium where c b g ˆ ˆ t=0 t=0 ∞ R−j (¯t+j + τt+j − yt+j ) c ˆ ˆt = b (10.3.7) j=0 and ∞ ˆ Bt = R−j (ˆt+j − gt+j ) τ ¯ (10.3.8) j=0 Proof: The first point of the proposition is that the same consumption plan {¯t }∞ , but adjusted borrowing plan {ˆt+1 }∞ , solve the household’s optimum c t=0 b t=0 problem under the altered government tax scheme Under the natural debt limit, the household in effect faces a single intertemporal budget constraint (10.3.4 ) At time , the household can be thought of as choosing an optimal consumption plan subject to the single constraint, ∞ −t ∞ R (ct − yt ) + b0 = t=0 R−t τt t=0 Thus, the household’s budget set, and therefore its optimal plan, does not depend on the timing of taxes, only their present value The altered tax plan leaves the household’s intertemporal budget set unaltered and therefore doesn’t 312 Ricardian Equivalence affect its optimal consumption plan Next, we construct the adjusted borrowing plan {ˆt+1 }∞ by solving the budget constraint (10.3.3 ) forward to obtain b t=0 (10.3.7 ) The adjusted borrowing plan satisfies trivially the (adjusted) natural debt limit in every period, since the consumption plan {¯t }∞ is a nonnegative c t=0 sequence The second point of the proposition is that the altered government tax and borrowing plans continue to satisfy the government’s budget constraint In particular, we see that the government’s budget set at time does not depend on the timing of taxes, only their present value, ∞ R−t τt − B0 = t=0 ∞ R−t gt t=0 Thus, under the altered tax plan with an unchanged present value of taxes, the government can finance the same expenditure plan {¯t }∞ The adjusted g t=0 ˆt+1 }∞ is computed in a similar way as above to arrive at borrowing plan {B t=0 (10.3.8 ) It is straightforward to verify that the adjusted borrowing plan {ˆ }∞ bt+1 t=0 must satisfy the transversality condition (10.2.4 ) In any period (k − 1) ≥ , solving the budget constraint (10.3.3 ) backward yields k Rj [yk−j − τk−j − ck−j ] + Rk b0 bk = j=1 Evidently, the difference between ¯k of the initial equilibrium and ˆk is equal b b to k ¯k − ˆk = b b Rj [ˆk−j − τk−j ] , τ ¯ j=1 and after multiplying both sides by R1−k , k−1 R−t [ˆt − τt ] τ ¯ R1−k ¯k − ˆk = R b b t=0 The limit of the right side is zero when k goes to infinity due to condition (10.3.6 ), and hence, the fact that the equilibrium borrowing plan {¯t+1 }∞ b t=0 ˆt+1 }∞ satisfies transversality condition (10.2.4 ) implies that so must {b t=0 Government 313 This proposition depends on imposing the natural debt limit, which is weaker than the no-borrowing constraint on the household Under the noborrowing constraint, we require that the asset choice bt+1 at time t both satisfies budget constraint (10.3.3 ) and does not fall below zero That is, under the no-borrowing constraint, we have to check more than just a single intertemporal budget constraint for the household at time Changes in the timing of taxes that obey equation (10.3.6 ) evidently alter the right side of equation (10.3.3 ) and can, for example, cause a previously binding borrowing constraint no longer to be binding, and vice versa Binding borrowing constraints in either the initial {¯t }∞ equilibrium or the new {ˆt }∞ equilibria eliminates a Riτ t=0 τ t=0 cardian proposition as general as Proposition More restricted versions of the proposition evidently hold across restricted equivalence classes of taxes that not alter when the borrowing constraints are binding across the two equilibria being compared Proposition 2: Consider an initial equilibrium with consumption path {¯t }∞ in which bt+1 > for all t ≥ Let {¯t }∞ be the tax rate in the c t=0 τ t=0 initial equilibrium, and let {ˆt }∞ be any other tax-rate sequence for which τ t=0 ∞ ˆt = b R−j (¯t+j + τt+j − yt+j ) ≥ c ˆ j=0 τ t=0 for all t ≥ Then {¯t }∞ is also an equilibrium allocation for the {ˆt }∞ tax c t=0 sequence We leave the proof of this proposition to the reader 314 Ricardian Equivalence 10.4 Linked generations interpretation Much of the preceding analysis with borrowing constraints applies to a setting with overlapping generations linked by a bequest motive Assume that there is a sequence of one-period-lived agents For each t ≥ there is a one-period-lived agent who values consumption and the utility of his direct descendant, a young person at time t + Preferences of a young person at t are ordered by u(ct ) + βV (bt+1 ), where u(c) is the same utility function as in the previous section, bt+1 ≥ are bequests from the time- t person to the time– t + person, and V (bt+1 ) is the maximized utility function of a time–t + agent The maximized utility function is defined recursively by V (bt ) = max {u(ct ) + βV (bt+1 )}∞ t=0 ct ,bt+1 (10.4.1) where the maximization is subject to ct + R−1 bt+1 ≤ yt − τt + bt (10.4.2) and bt+1 ≥ The constraint bt+1 ≥ requires that bequests cannot be negative Notice that a person cares about his direct descendant, but not vice versa We continue to assume that there is an infinitely lived government whose taxes and purchasing and borrowing strategies are as described in the previous section In consumption outcomes, this model is equivalent to the previous model with a no-borrowing constraint Bequests here play the role of savings bt+1 in the previous model A positive savings condition bt+1 > in the previous version of the model becomes an “operational bequest motive” in the overlapping generations model It follows that we can obtain a restricted Ricardian equivalence proposition, qualified as in Proposition The qualification is that the initial equilibrium must have an operational bequest motive for all t ≥ , and that the new tax policy must not be so different from the initial one that it renders the bequest motive inoperative Concluding remarks 315 10.5 Concluding remarks The arguments in this chapter were cast in a setting with an exogenous interest rate R and a capital market that is outside of the model When we discussed potential failures of Ricardian equivalence due to households facing no-borrowing constraints, we were also implicitly contemplating changes in the government’s outside asset position For example, consider an altered tax plan {ˆt }∞ that τ t=0 satisfies (10.3.6 ) and shifts taxes away from the future toward the present A large enough change will definitely ensure that the government is a lender in early periods But since the households are not allowed to become indebted, the government must lend abroad and we can show that Ricardian equivalence breaks down The readers might be able to anticipate the nature of the general equilibrium proof of Ricardian equivalence in chapter 13 First, private consumption and government expenditures must then be consistent with the aggregate endowment in each period, ct + gt = yt , which implies that an altered tax plan cannot affect the consumption allocation as long as government expenditures are kept the same Second, interest rates are determined by intertemporal marginal rates of substitution evaluated at the equilibrium consumption allocation, as studied in chapter Hence, an unchanged consumption allocation implies that interest rates are also unchanged Third, at those very interest rates, it can be shown that households would like to choose asset positions that exactly offset any changes in the government’s asset holdings implied by an altered tax plan For example, in the case of the tax change contemplated in the preceding paragraph, the households would demand loans exactly equal to the rise in government lending generated by budget surpluses in early periods The households would use those loans to meet the higher taxes and thereby finance an unchanged consumption plan The finding of Ricardian equivalence in the infinitely lived agent model is a useful starting point for identifying alternative assumptions under which the irrelevance result might fail to hold, such as our imposition of borrowing constraints that are tighter than the “natural debt limit” Another deviation from the benchmark model is finitely lived agents, as analyzed by Diamond (1965) and Blanchard (1985) But as suggested by Barro (1974) and shown in this Seater (1993) reviews the theory and empirical evidence on Ricardian equivalence 316 Ricardian Equivalence chapter, Ricardian equivalence will still continue to hold if agents are altruistic towards their descendants and there is an operational bequest motive Bernheim and Bagwell (1988) take this argument to its extreme and formulate a model where all agents become interconnected because of linkages across dynastic families, which is shown to render neutral all redistributive policies including distortionary taxes But in general, replacing lump sum taxes by distortionary taxes is a sure way to undo Ricardian equivalence, see e.g Barsky, Mankiw and Zeldes (1986) We will return to the question of the timing of distortionary taxes in chapter 15 Kimball and Mankiw (1989) describe how incomplete markets can make the timing of taxes interact with a precautionary savings motive in a way that does away with Ricardian equivalence We take up precautionary savings and incomplete markets in chapters 16 and 17 Finally, by allowing distorting taxes to be history dependent, Bassetto and Kocherlakota (2004) attain a Ricardian equivalence result for a variety of taxes ... (10. 2.2 ), ct + R−1 bt+1 ≤ yt − τt + bt (10. 3.3) Solving this tax-adjusted budget constraint forward and invoking transversality condition (10. 2.4 ) yield ∞ bt = R−j (ct+j + τt+j − yt+j ) (10. 3.4)... generations linked by a bequest motive Assume that there is a sequence of one-period-lived agents For each t ≥ there is a one-period-lived agent who values consumption and the utility of his direct descendant,... pression (10. 2.1 ) subject to (10. 2.2 ) and bt+1 ≥ for all t The first-order conditions for this problem are u (ct ) ≥ βRu (ct+1 ), ∀t ≥ 0; (10. 2.6a) and u (ct ) > βRu (ct+1 ) implies bt+1 = (10. 2.6b)

Ngày đăng: 04/07/2014, 15:20

Tài liệu cùng người dùng

  • Đang cập nhật ...

Tài liệu liên quan